Quản trị kinh doanh - Chapter 13: Market structure and competition

Assumptions Firms set outputs (quantities)* Homogeneous Products Simultaneous Non-cooperative *Definition: In a Cournot game, each firm sets its output (quantity) taking as given the output level of its competitor(s), so as to maximize profits. Price adjusts according to demand. Residual Demand: Firm i's guess about its rival's output determines its residual demand.

pptx65 trang | Chia sẻ: huyhoang44 | Lượt xem: 504 | Lượt tải: 0download
Bạn đang xem trước 20 trang tài liệu Quản trị kinh doanh - Chapter 13: Market structure and competition, để xem tài liệu hoàn chỉnh bạn click vào nút DOWNLOAD ở trên
1Market Structureand CompetitionChapter 13Copyright (c)2014 John Wiley & Sons, Inc.2Chapter Thirteen OverviewIntroduction: Cola WarsA Taxonomy of Market StructuresMonopolistic CompetitionOligopoly – Interdependence of Strategic DecisionsBertrand with Homogeneous and Differentiated ProductsThe Effect of a Change in the Strategic VariableTheory vs. ObservationCournot Equilibrium (homogeneous)Comparison to Bertrand, MonopolyReconciling Bertrand, and CournotThe Effect of a Change in Timing: Stackelberg EquilibriumChapter ThirteenCopyright (c)2014 John Wiley & Sons, Inc.3Chapter ThirteenMarket Structures• The number of sellers• The number of buyers• Entry conditions• The degree of product differentiationFour Key DimensionsCopyright (c)2014 John Wiley & Sons, Inc.4Chapter ThirteenProduct DifferentiationDefinition: Product Differentiation between two or more products exists when the products possess attributes that, in the minds of consumers, set the products apart from one another and make them less than perfect substitutes.Examples: Pepsi is sweeter than Coke, Brand Name batteries last longer than "generic" batteries.Copyright (c)2014 John Wiley & Sons, Inc.5Chapter ThirteenProduct Differentiation "Superiority" (Vertical Product Differentiation) i.e. one product is viewed as unambiguously better than another so that, at the same price, all consumers would buy the better product "Substitutability" (Horizontal Product Differentiation) i.e. at the same price, some consumers would prefer the characteristics of product A while other consumers would prefer the characteristics of product B.Copyright (c)2014 John Wiley & Sons, Inc.6Chapter ThirteenTypes of Market StructuresCopyright (c)2014 John Wiley & Sons, Inc.7Chapter ThirteenOligopolyAssumptions: Many Buyers and Few Sellers Each firm faces downward-sloping demand because each is a large producer compared to the total market size There is no one dominant model of oligopoly. We will review several.Copyright (c)2014 John Wiley & Sons, Inc.8Chapter ThirteenCournot OligopolyAssumptions Firms set outputs (quantities)* Homogeneous Products Simultaneous Non-cooperative*Definition: In a Cournot game, each firm sets its output (quantity) taking as given the output level of its competitor(s), so as to maximize profits.Price adjusts according to demand.Residual Demand: Firm i's guess about its rival's output determines its residual demand.Copyright (c)2014 John Wiley & Sons, Inc.9Chapter ThirteenSimultaneously vs. Non-cooperativelyDefinition: Firms act simultaneously if each firm makes its strategic decision at the same time, without prior observation of the other firm's decision.Definition: Firms act non-cooperatively if they set strategy independently, without colluding with the other firm in any way Copyright (c)2014 John Wiley & Sons, Inc.10Chapter ThirteenDefinition: The relationship between the price charged by firm i and the demand firm i faces is firm is residual demandIn other words, the residual demand of firm i is the market demand minus the amount of demand fulfilled by other firms in the market: Q1 = Q - Q2Residual DemandCopyright (c)2014 John Wiley & Sons, Inc.11PriceQuantity0DemandResidual Demand when q2 = 10 10 unitsResidual Marginal Revenue when q2 = 10MCq1* Chapter ThirteenResidual DemandCopyright (c)2014 John Wiley & Sons, Inc.12Chapter ThirteenProfit MaximizationProfit Maximization: Each firm acts as a monopolist on its residual demand curve, equating MRr to MC.MRr = p + q1(p/q) = MCBest Response Function: The point where (residual) marginal revenue equals marginal cost gives the best response of firm i to its rival's (rivals') actions.For every possible output of the rival(s), we can determine firm i's best response. The sum of all these points makes up the best response (reaction) function of firm i.Copyright (c)2014 John Wiley & Sons, Inc.13q1Reaction Function of Firm 10Reaction Function of Firm 2q1*q2*•Chapter Thirteenq2Profit MaximizationExample: Reaction Functions, Quantity SettingCopyright (c)2014 John Wiley & Sons, Inc.14Chapter ThirteenP = 100 - Q1 - Q2MC = AC = 10What is firm 1's profit-maximizing output when firm 2 produces 50?Firm 1's residual demand: P = (100 - 50) - Q1 MR50 = 50 - 2Q1 MR50 = MC  50 - 2Q1 = 10EquilibriumEquilibrium: No firm has an incentive to deviate in equilibrium in the sense that each firm is maximizing profits given its rival's outputWhat is the equation of firm 1's reaction function?Firm 1's residual demand: P = (100 - Q2) - Q1 MRr = 100 - Q2 - 2Q1 MRr = MC  100 - Q2 - 2Q1 = 10 Q1r = 45 - Q2/2 firm 1's reaction functionSimilarly, one can compute that Q2r = 45 - Q1/2Copyright (c)2014 John Wiley & Sons, Inc.15Chapter ThirteenProfit MaximizationNow, calculate the Cournot equilibrium. Q1 = 45 - (45 - Q1/2)/2 Q1* = 30 Q2* = 30 P* = 40 1* = 2* = 30(30) = 900Copyright (c)2014 John Wiley & Sons, Inc.16Chapter ThirteenBertrand Oligopoly (homogeneous)Assumptions: Firms set price* Homogeneous product Simultaneous Non-cooperative*Definition: In a Bertrand oligopoly, each firm sets its price, taking as given the price(s) set by other firm(s), so as to maximize profits.Copyright (c)2014 John Wiley & Sons, Inc.17Chapter Thirteen Homogeneity implies that consumers will buy from the low-price seller. Further, each firm realizes that the demand that it faces depends both on its own price and on the price set by other firms Specifically, any firm charging a higher price than its rivals will sell no output. Any firm charging a lower price than its rivals will obtain the entire market demand. Setting PriceCopyright (c)2014 John Wiley & Sons, Inc.18QuantityPriceMarket Demand•Residual Demand Curve (thickened line segments)0Chapter ThirteenResidual Demand Curve – Price SettingCopyright (c)2014 John Wiley & Sons, Inc.19Chapter ThirteenResidual Demand Curve – Price Setting Assume firm always meets its residual demand (no capacity constraints) Assume that marginal cost is constant at c per unit. Hence, any price at least equal to c ensures non-negative profits.AssumptionsCopyright (c)2014 John Wiley & Sons, Inc.20Chapter ThirteenBest Response FunctionEach firm's profit maximizing response to the other firm's price is to undercut (as long as P > MC)Definition: The firm's profit maximizing action as a function of the action by the rival firm is the firm's best response (or reaction) function Example:2 firmsBertrand competitorsFirm 1's best response function is P1=P2- eFirm 2's best response function is P2=P1- eCopyright (c)2014 John Wiley & Sons, Inc.21Chapter ThirteenEquilibriumIf we assume no capacity constraints and that all firms have the same constant average and marginal cost of c then:For each firm's response to be a best response to the other's each firm must undercut the other as long as P> MCWhere does this stop? P = MC (!)Copyright (c)2014 John Wiley & Sons, Inc.22Chapter ThirteenEquilibrium1. Firms price at marginal cost2. Firms make zero profits3. The number of firms is irrelevant to the price level as long as more than one firm is present: two firms is enough to replicate the perfectly competitive outcome.Essentially, the assumption of no capacity constraints combined with a constant average and marginal cost takes the place of free entry.Key PointsCopyright (c)2014 John Wiley & Sons, Inc.23Chapter ThirteenStackelberg model of oligopoly is a situation in which one firm acts as a quantity leader, choosing its quantity first, with all other firms acting as followers.Call the first mover the “leader” and the second mover the “follower”. The second firm is in the same situation as a Cournot firm: it takes the leader’s output as given and maximizes profits accordingly, using its residual demand.The second firm’s behavior can, then, be summarized by a Cournot reaction function.Stackelberg OligopolyCopyright (c)2014 John Wiley & Sons, Inc.24q1q2Follower’s Cournot Reaction Function•Former Cournot Equilibrium•••A B(q1= 90)CProfit for firm 1 at A0 at B0 at C1012.5at Cournot Eq900 Chapter ThirteenStackelberg Equilibrium vs. CournotCopyright (c)2014 John Wiley & Sons, Inc.25Chapter ThirteenA single company with an overwhelming market share (a dominant firm) competes against many small producers (competitive fringe), each of whom has a small market share.Limit Pricing – a strategy whereby the dominant firm keeps its price below the level that maximizes its current profit in order to reduce the rate of expansion by the fringe.Dominant Firm MarketsCopyright (c)2014 John Wiley & Sons, Inc.26Chapter ThirteenBertrand Competition – DifferentiatedAssumptions:Firms set price*Differentiated productSimultaneous Non-cooperative*Differentiation means that lowering price below your rivals' will not result in capturing the entire market, nor will raising price mean losing the entire market so that residual demand decreases smoothlyCopyright (c)2014 John Wiley & Sons, Inc.27Chapter ThirteenQ1 = 100 - 2P1 + P2 "Coke's demand"Q2 = 100 - 2P2 + P1 "Pepsi's demand"MC1 = MC2 = 5What is firm 1's residual demand when Firm 2's price is $10? $0? Q1(10) = 100 - 2P1 + 10 = 110 - 2P1Q1(0) = 100 - 2P1 + 0 = 100 - 2P1 Bertrand Competition – DifferentiatedExampleCopyright (c)2014 John Wiley & Sons, Inc.28Coke’s PriceMR0Pepsi’s price = $0 for D0 and $10 for D100100Chapter ThirteenResidual Demand, Price Setting, Differentiated Products Each firm maximizes profits based on its residual demand by setting MR (based on residual demand) = MCKey ConceptsCoke’s QuantityCopyright (c)2014 John Wiley & Sons, Inc.290110100D0D10Chapter ThirteenKey ConceptsPepsi’s price = $0 for D0 and $10 for D10Residual Demand, Price Setting, Differentiated Products Each firm maximizes profits based on its residual demand by setting MR (based on residual demand) = MCCoke’s PriceCoke’s QuantityCopyright (c)2014 John Wiley & Sons, Inc.30Coke’s QuantityMR0D00MR10110100D10Chapter ThirteenKey ConceptsPepsi’s price = $0 for D0 and $10 for D10Residual Demand, Price Setting, Differentiated Products Each firm maximizes profits based on its residual demand by setting MR (based on residual demand) = MCCoke’s PriceCopyright (c)2014 John Wiley & Sons, Inc.315MR0D00D10MR10110100Chapter ThirteenKey ConceptsPepsi’s price = $0 for D0 and $10 for D10Residual Demand, Price Setting, Differentiated Products Each firm maximizes profits based on its residual demand by setting MR (based on residual demand) = MCCoke’s PriceCoke’s QuantityCopyright (c)2014 John Wiley & Sons, Inc.32527.5MR0D00D10MR103045 50110100Chapter ThirteenKey ConceptsKey ConceptsPepsi’s price = $0 for D0 and $10 for D10Residual Demand, Price Setting, Differentiated Products Each firm maximizes profits based on its residual demand by setting MR (based on residual demand) = MCCoke’s PriceCoke’s QuantityCopyright (c)2014 John Wiley & Sons, Inc.33Chapter ThirteenKey ConceptsResidual Demand, Price Setting, Differentiated Products Each firm maximizes profits based on its residual demand by setting MR (based on residual demand) = MCExample: MR1(10) = 55 - Q1(10) = 5Q1(10) = 50P1(10) = 30Therefore, firm 1's best response to a price of $10 by firm 2 is a price of $30Copyright (c)2014 John Wiley & Sons, Inc.34Chapter ThirteenKey ConceptsResidual Demand, Price Setting, Differentiated Products Each firm maximizes profits based on its residual demand by setting MR (based on residual demand) = MCExample: Solving for firm 1's reaction function for any arbitrary price by firm 2P1 = 50 - Q1/2 + P2/2MR = 50 - Q1 + P2/2MR = MC => Q1 = 45 + P2/2Copyright (c)2014 John Wiley & Sons, Inc.35Chapter ThirteenAnd, using the demand curve, we have: P1 = 50 + P2/2 - 45/2 - P2/4 or P1 = 27.5 + P2/4 the reaction functionKey ConceptsResidual Demand, Price Setting, Differentiated Products Each firm maximizes profits based on its residual demand by setting MR (based on residual demand) = MCCopyright (c)2014 John Wiley & Sons, Inc.36Pepsi’sPrice (P2)Coke’s Price (P1)P2 = 27.5 + P1/4(Pepsi’s R.F.)27.5Chapter ThirteenEquilibrium and Reaction FunctionsPrice Setting and Differentiated ProductsCopyright (c)2014 John Wiley & Sons, Inc.37P1 = 27.5 + P2/4 (Coke’s R.F.)P2 = 27.5 + P1/4(Pepsi’s R.F.)•27.527.5Chapter ThirteenPepsi’sPrice (P2)Coke’s Price (P1)Equilibrium and Reaction FunctionsPrice Setting and Differentiated ProductsP1 = 110/3Copyright (c)2014 John Wiley & Sons, Inc.38P2 = 110/3•BertrandEquilibrium27.5Chapter ThirteenPepsi’sPrice (P2)Coke’s Price (P1)P2 = 27.5 + P1/4(Pepsi’s R.F.)P1 = 27.5 + P2/4 (Coke’s R.F.)Equilibrium and Reaction FunctionsPrice Setting and Differentiated ProductsP1 = 110/327.5Copyright (c)2014 John Wiley & Sons, Inc.39Chapter ThirteenEquilibrium occurs when all firms simultaneously choose their best response to each others' actions. Graphically, this amounts to the point where the best response functions cross.EquilibriumCopyright (c)2014 John Wiley & Sons, Inc.40Chapter ThirteenExample: Firm 1 and Firm 2, continued P1 = 27.5 + P2/4 P2 = 27.5 + P1/4Solving these two equations in two unknowns. P1* = P2* = 110/3Plugging these prices into demand, we have: Q1* = Q2* = 190/3 1* = 2* = 2005.55  = 4011.10EquilibriumCopyright (c)2014 John Wiley & Sons, Inc.41Chapter ThirteenProfits are positive in equilibrium since both prices are above marginal cost!Even if we have no capacity constraints, and constant marginal cost, a firm cannot capture all demand by cutting price.This blunts price-cutting incentives and means that the firms' own behavior does not mimic free entryEquilibriumNotice That:Copyright (c)2014 John Wiley & Sons, Inc.42Chapter ThirteenEquilibriumNotice That:Only if I were to let the number of firms approach infinity would price approach marginal cost.Prices need not be equal in equilibrium if firms not identical (e.g. Marginal costs differ implies that prices differ)The reaction functions slope upward: "aggression => aggression"Copyright (c)2014 John Wiley & Sons, Inc.43Chapter ThirteenCournot, Bertrand, and Monopoly EquilibriumsP > MC for Cournot competitors, but P 100 - 2Q = 10 => QM = 45 PM = 55 M= 45(45) = 2025 c = 1800Copyright (c)2014 John Wiley & Sons, Inc.44Chapter ThirteenA perfectly collusive industry takes into account that an increase in output by one firm depresses the profits of the other firm(s) in the industry. A Cournot competitor takes into account the effect of the increase in output on its own profits only. Therefore, Cournot competitors "overproduce" relative to the collusive (monopoly) point. Further, this problem gets "worse" as the number of competitors grows because the market share of each individual firm falls, increasing the difference between the private gain from increasing production and the profit destruction effect on rivals.Therefore, the more concentrated the industry in the Cournot case, the higher the price-cost margin.Cournot, Bertrand, and Monopoly EquilibriumsCopyright (c)2014 John Wiley & Sons, Inc.45Chapter ThirteenHomogeneous product Bertrand resulted in zero profits, whereas the Cournot case resulted in positive profits. Why?The best response functions in the Cournot model slope downward. In other words, the more aggressive a rival (in terms of output), the more passive the Cournot firm's response.The best response functions in the Bertrand model slope upward. In other words, the more aggressive a rival (in terms of price) the more aggressive the Bertrand firm's response.Cournot, Bertrand, and Monopoly EquilibriumsCopyright (c)2014 John Wiley & Sons, Inc.46Chapter ThirteenCournot: Suppose firm j raises its outputthe price at which firm i can sell output falls. This means that the incentive to increase output falls as the output of the competitor rises.Bertrand: Suppose firm j raises price the price at which firm i can sell output rises. As long as firm's price is less than firm's, the incentive to increase price will depend on the (market) marginal revenue.Cournot, Bertrand, and Monopoly EquilibriumsCopyright (c)2014 John Wiley & Sons, Inc.47Example: Restaurants, Local markets for doctorsChapter ThirteenChamberlinian Monopolistic CompetitionMarket Structure Many Buyers Many Sellers Free entry and Exit (Horizontal) Product DifferentiationWhen firms have horizontally differentiated products, they each face downward-sloping demand for their product because a small change in price will not cause ALL buyers to switch to another firm's product.Copyright (c)2014 John Wiley & Sons, Inc.48Chapter Thirteen1. Each firm is small each takes the observed "market price" as given in its production decisions.2. Since market price may not stay given, the firm's perceived demand may differ from its actual demand.3.If all firms' prices fall the same amount, no customers switch supplier but the total market consumption grows.4. If only one firm's price falls, it steals customers from other firms as well as increases total market consumptionMonopolistic Competition – Short RunCopyright (c)2014 John Wiley & Sons, Inc.49PriceQuantityd (PA=20)Chapter ThirteenPerceived vs. Actual DemandCopyright (c)2014 John Wiley & Sons, Inc.50d (PA=50)d (PA=20)Demand assuming no price matchingChapter ThirteenPriceQuantityPerceived vs. Actual DemandCopyright (c)2014 John Wiley & Sons, Inc.51d (PA=50)d (PA=20)Demand (assuming price matching by all firms)50•Chapter ThirteenPriceQuantityPerceived vs. Actual DemandDemand assuming no price matchingCopyright (c)2014 John Wiley & Sons, Inc.52Chapter ThirteenMarket EquilibriumThe market is in equilibrium if: Each firm maximizes profit taking the average market price as given Each firm can sell the quantity it desires at the actual average market price that prevailsCopyright (c)2014 John Wiley & Sons, Inc.53PriceQuantityd(PA=43)Chapter ThirteenShort Run Chamberlinian EquilibriumCopyright (c)2014 John Wiley & Sons, Inc.54Quantityd (PA=50)Demand assuming no price matchingd(PA=43)Chapter ThirteenPriceShort Run Chamberlinian EquilibriumCopyright (c)2014 John Wiley & Sons, Inc.55Quantityd (PA=50)Demand (assuming price matching by all firms P=PA)Demand assuming no price matching•d(PA=43)•Chapter ThirteenPriceShort Run Chamberlinian EquilibriumCopyright (c)2014 John Wiley & Sons, Inc.56Quantityd (PA=50)Demand (assuming price matching by all firms P=PA)Demand assuming no price matching50•d(PA=43)•43MR43mc5715Chapter ThirteenPriceShort Run Chamberlinian EquilibriumCopyright (c)2014 John Wiley & Sons, Inc.57Chapter ThirteenShort Run Monopolistically Competitive EquilibriumComputing Short Run Monopolistically Competitive Equilibrium MC = $15 N = 100 Q = 100 - 2P + PA Where: PA is the average market price N is the number of firmsCopyright (c)2014 John Wiley & Sons, Inc.58Chapter ThirteenShort Run Monopolistically Competitive EquilibriumA. What is the equation of d40? What is the equation of D? d40: Qd = 100 - 2P + 40 = 140 - 2P D: Note that P = PA so that QD = 100 - PB. Show that d40 and D intersect at P = 40 P = 40 => Qd = 140 - 80 = 60 QD = 100 - 40 = 60C. For any given average price, PA, find a typical firm's profit maximizing quantityCopyright (c)2014 John Wiley & Sons, Inc.59Chapter ThirteenInverse Perceived DemandP = 50 - (1/2)Q + (1/2)PA MR = 50 - Q + (1/2)PAMR = MC => 50 - Q + (1/2)PA = 15Qe = 35 + (1/2)PA Pe = 50 - (1/2)Qe + (1/2)PA Pe = 32.5 + (1/4)PACopyright (c)2014 John Wiley & Sons, Inc.60Chapter ThirteenShort Run Monopolistically Competitive EquilibriumD. What is the short run equilibrium price in this industry?In equilibrium, Qe = QD at PA so that100 - PA = 35 + (1/2)PAPA = 43.33Qe = 56.66QD = 56.66Copyright (c)2014 John Wiley & Sons, Inc.61Chapter ThirteenMonopolistic Competition in the Long RunAt the short run equilibrium P > AC so that each firm may make positive profit.Entry shifts d and D left until average industry price equals average cost.This is long run equilibrium is represented graphically by:MR = MC for each firmD = d at the average market priced and AC are tangent at average market priceCopyright (c)2014 John Wiley & Sons, Inc.62Average CostQuantityPriceResidual Demand shifts in as entry occursMarginal Costq*P*q**P**MRChapter ThirteenLong Run Chamberlinian EquilibriumCopyright (c)2014 John Wiley & Sons, Inc.63Chapter ThirteenSummary1. Market structures are characterized by the number of buyers, the number of sellers, the degree of product differentiation and the entry conditions.2. Product differentiation alone or a small number of competitors alone is not enough to destroy the long run zero profit result of perfect competition. This was illustrated with the Chamberlinian and Bertrand models.3. Chamberlinian) monopolistic competition assumes that there are many buyers, many sellers, differentiated products and free entry in the long run.Copyright (c)2014 John Wiley & Sons, Inc.64Chapter ThirteenSummary4. Chamberlinian sellers face downward-sloping demand but are price takers (i.e. they do not perceive that their change in price will affect the average price level). Profits may be positive in the short run but free entry drives profits to zero in the long run.5. Bertrand and Cournot competition assume that there are many buyers, few sellers, and homogeneous or differentiated products. Firms compete in price in Bertrand oligopoly and in quantity in Cournot oligopoly.6. Bertrand and Cournot competitors take into account their strategic interdependence by means of constructing a best response schedule: each firm maximizes profits given the rival's strategy.Copyright (c)2014 John Wiley & Sons, Inc.65Chapter ThirteenSummary7. Equilibrium in such a setting requires that all firms be on their best response functions.8. If the products are homogeneous, the Bertrand equilibrium results in zero profits. By changing the strategic variable from price to quantity, we obtain much higher prices (and profits). Further, the results are sensitive to the assumption of simultaneous moves. 9. This result can be traced to the slope of the reaction functions: upwards in the case of Bertrand and downwards in the case of Cournot. These slopes imply that "aggressivity" results in a "passive" response in the Cournot case and an "aggressive" response in the Bertrand case.Copyright (c)2014 John Wiley & Sons, Inc.

Các file đính kèm theo tài liệu này:

  • pptxch13_4038.pptx