CONCLUSION
The goals of competition law and policy play a notable
navigator in law enforcement and lead to new rule inauguration regimes. However, Vietnam avoids signifying its goals in all two competition law versions, the
VCL 2004 and the recent VCL 2018. There appears
an increasing debate in the academic world in which
competition law goals have been outlined in several
ways.
Indeed, Vietnam has a demand to look at more developed countries for future policies to harmonize
merger control law. According to some experts,
Japan’s experience can “provide useful lessons” for
developing countries or transitional economies94.u
Moreover, Japan is the leading country participating
in merger deals in Vietnam, which is forecasted to
continue in the coming years95–97. Aside from the
US, Japan, and the EU merger regulations, there are
suitable choices in a comparative study.
Overall, it implies that Vietnam, in its current
progress, could remain the diverse objectives for competition law enforcement. Under the approach to plural interests, Vietnam must identify ones, or only one,
for priority. From other legal systems’ perspectives, it
sounds that Vietnam should mainly direct the “effective competition” particularly experienced from the
EU’s aspect. Traditionally, the “free and fair competition” may be fluently perceived, but it seems too abstract and outdated. The formula of workable competition could supply significant aspects that impact
the enhancement of firms’ competitiveness. Finally,
consumer welfare could have remained for further
achievements. At present, effective competition could
partially target this goal.
14 trang |
Chia sẻ: hachi492 | Ngày: 13/01/2022 | Lượt xem: 304 | Lượt tải: 0
Bạn đang xem nội dung tài liệu A comparative study on goals of competition law with the case of merger regulation and recommendations to Viet Nam, để tải tài liệu về máy bạn click vào nút DOWNLOAD ở trên
research, it was one of three
underlying regimes of Japanese anti-monopoly law’s
objectives extracted from Art. 138.i According to Iy-
ori Hiroshi, like what Masako analyzed, the JAA con-
ducts this aim mainly to restrict “unreasonable re-
straint of trade” under chapter II, which takes place
for the private monopolization39. Japanese merger
regulation later made it divergent for the definition of
“unreasonable restraint of trade” from this aspect. In
reality, the interpretation of this phenomenon under
the Japanese perspective has been different from the
US’s application of a similar test under the Sherman
Act39.
Overall, what is addressed in Art.1 makes sense
regarding the goals of the Japanese anti-monopoly
regime. Among the diversity of critical objectives, the
promotion of “fair and free competition” seems to be
the underlying principle due to its initial statement
in the Article and its clear definition in the Art. 2 4.j
And, the phrase “and thereby secure the interests
of general consumers” (40 Art. 1) could mean that
the protection of consumer’s interests remains signif-
icant and becomes a priority even though it has not
appeared frequently41,42.
Regarding how this objective locates, one could rec-
ognize that it has resulted from the foremost goals
and the specific branch of law. In the merger reg-
ulation, the JFTC’s Merger Guidelines sounds to be
familiar with the US approach. Explicitly, it defined
themarket power, or the outcomes of “lessening com-
petition,” raised by the merger as consequences of
decreasing output, diminishing innovation, or oth-
erwise harmful conditions to customers rather than
what is expressed in general in the Art. 2 4 (34 Sec.
1,43 Part III.1.B.).
Japan has a sophisticated approach in determining
the goals for the anti-monopoly law. The interpreta-
tion needs more practical aspects, which could make
iTwo other regimes consist of the promotion of fair and free com-
petition and the protection of consumers’ interests.
j“the JAA” Art. 1 & 2.
1257
Science & Technology Development Journal – Economics - Law andManagement, 5(1):1253-1266
Japan’s direction altered in practice because of, for ex-
ample, the various targets in economic development,
especially the incentives for industrial policy. There-
fore, it contributes to supply the diversity for Japan’s
approach even though it seems to approach the pro-
tection of consumer welfare like the US.
On the EU inauguration of effective compe-
tition
It would not be too strict in tackling the EU competi-
tion law’s goals. Initially, in almost all situations, the
discussions first and foremost mentioned the EU’s at-
tempts in making rules for the protection of compe-
tition, particularly the process of competition, then
moved to the other afterward. Overall, the EU’s fun-
damental competition rules were for the “vibrant and
competitive economy”44,45.
On the one hand, the experts applied the competition
policy to the “allocative efficiency” 46. When there ap-
peared problems, notably raised on the neo-classical
economic theory of perfect competition, on the other
hand, the emphasis gave a movement, even from the
“fairness and economic freedom,” for the workable
competition, or contestable markets1,47–49.k Ulti-
mately, the concept of “effective competition,” the
best imperfect competition,” stops the arguments as
a significant achievement for the EU’s competition
law48–50.
The most crucial legal inclusions for this aim are the
legal documents for competition law in the EU. From
the ECT to the TFEU, the EU has remained to re-
gard “competition,” notably the “fair competition”
on the preamble51.l However, in practice, the EU
court expanded the objective to the “effective com-
petition”52,53. As a result, for this goal, both the EU
Merger Regulation 1989 and the EU Merger Regula-
tion 2004 attempt to combat incompatiblemergers for
“the need to maintain and develop effective compe-
tition in the common market”54,55.m This objective
accordingly has spread broadly till now.
Notwithstanding, the ongoing discussion emphasizes
the EU’s competition law to address consumer wel-
fare19,20,48. The EU merger regulation could not lose
this pathway on direction against the adverse effects
of the marker power or monopolization56. Therefore,
the arguments suggest that the merger’s substantive
test mostly concerns consumers’ “expense” on antic-
ipating its anti-competitive effects57. In other words,
kThe goals were frequently mentioned before the EU economic
modernization.
lArt. 81,52 Art. 85,53 Art. 102.
mFor example, recital 14 for the former citation and the recital 23
for the latter one.
competition agencies must evaluate the merger based
on “its impact on consumer surplus”58, and the appli-
cation of remedies for anti-competitive mergers pro-
vide a matching contribution59.
The others also prove the multi-approaches in out-
lining the EU competition law’s goals50,60,61.n Re-
cently, Gerbrandy Anna has ever based the discussion
on the EU “economic constitution” to aim the goals
of competition law for its internal market modern-
ization. The study attempted to prove that it would
not be necessary only to bring the competition policy
for consumer protection47. In his Speech in 2001, the
previous Commissioner Mario Monti stated that “the
goal of competition policy, in all its aspects, is to pro-
tect consumer welfare bymaintaining a high degree of
competition in the common market.” He meant that,
on protecting consumers’ interests, the merger con-
trol would not be “against mergers that create more
efficient firms”62. Unsurprisingly familiar, Georges
Vallindas also concerned about the ultimate conse-
quence of reducing prices for consumers even men-
tioned the industrial policy with its promotion of “op-
tional allocation resources”46.
This aspect has attracted much attention and sup-
ports. On top of the writing, EstevaMosso Carles also
made sure that the merger control rules need to pre-
serve the “competitive market structures” along with
ensuring that “consumers fully enjoy the benefits of
competition63. Other scholars also considered the
consumer welfare “in the technical at all,” and require
the competitive process for the market. They inter-
preted that the allocative and productive efficiency of
such a process of effective competition also results in
consumer benefits48.
As a result, the EUMerger Guidelines 2004 and 2008,
for example, officially clarify that the “effective com-
petition” that the EU merger regulation aims to pro-
tect and preserve would “bring benefits to consumers”
ultimately ( 55 at para.8,60,64 at para.10,65). Under
Monti Giorgio’s observation, the EU moves towards
economic efficiency and consumer welfare other than
competition and the internal market’s integration1.o
In detail, the effective competition on the market
could contribute to the “low price, high-quality prod-
ucts, a wide selection of goods and services, and in-
novation” (64at para.10,66 at para.8). The protection
of competition in merger control, in turn, benefits
consumers regularly. As Johannes Laitenberger’s new
nAlso, it is impossible to identify the single goals of competition
law in either the US or the EU.
oAmong there “core” values of competition, market integration,
and economic efficiency, the EU in the past also aimed the last value
at consumer welfare.
1258
Science & Technology Development Journal – Economics - Law andManagement, 5(1):1253-1266
Speech, the EU competition law with its a-few-year-
old infant merger control ensures consumers’ profits
from products and services even though it has sup-
plied different thorough 25 years67.
It is practical to focus that the law’s individual goal
supplies the similarity and, particularly, differences
among legal systems. To a certain extent, along with
the specific diverse approaches, the common objec-
tives could converge these countries in theoretical and
practical aspects. Indeed, one could recognize the
conventional approach in competition law goals in
the EU from the US and Japan perspectives. In prac-
tice, the US’s “ideas, theories, and insights” affect the
cEU’s debate and even “rage over the application of
EU rules”49. For example, Georges Valindas has cited
Richard Posner for the recent discussion on “the only
legitimate aim of competition law”46,68.p
THEMANIFEST SKETCHOF
COMPETITION POLICY’S GOALS IN
VIETNAM
Thenecessaryemphasison thediverseobjec-
tives
To aim the law to restrictions on anti-competitive be-
haviors, monopolizing processes, and any activities
against the competitive environment, the explanation
on the bill of competition law’s adjustment in 2018 ex-
pressed that the new law on competition directs to the
protection of fair and justice competition and thereby
supply the driving force to economic development69.
Soon before, the bill also stated that competition law
needs to bring the goals to protect the enterprises’ and
consumers’ legal interests70. It sounds that the law
functions brighter than the previous version; how-
ever, as seniors, the bill was confusing in front of the
law’s multi goals. Of course, it could be simple to fol-
low the regimes of unified interest rather than plu-
ral ones, such as the workable competition concen-
tration as the Chicago school’s approach71. The selec-
tion comes with the reason that it is not always easy to
combine diverse objectives71. The convergence and
divergences of the US, Japan, and EU’s competition
regimes could tell meaningful stories.
The above discussion sounds that these three legal sys-
tems converge to protect consumer welfare at the end.
More excitingly, Japan and the EU are closer to their
multi-approaches in the competition law’s objectives,
even though the EU merely appears bright with the
statement that “effective competition brings benefits
pFor an historical perspective of the Chicago andHarvard Schools
to consumers,” for example, in its merger regulation
(64 at para.10,66 at para.8). The EU historical enforce-
ment also evidenced the consumer welfare in its con-
tribution44. Of course, it should note the small but
significant difference between the EU and Japan, in
which the EU regards the “effective competition” oth-
erwise the “fair and free competition” of Japan.
In actuality, the analysis of Japan’s approach above re-
veals that Japan has been unsurprisingly reflecting the
perspective of more complex plural interests. In Art.
1 of the JAA, Japan pronouns that the purpose of the
law is:
• to promote fair and free competition, stimulate
the creative initiative of enterprise, encourage
business activity, heighten the level of employ-
ment and actual national income, and thereby
promote the democratic and wholesome devel-
opment of the national economy as well as se-
cure the interests of general consumers ( 40 Art.
1).
In practice, several countries have turned the compe-
tition law to solve various problems like Japan and the
EU; however, they popularly highly select only one
concern as the priority3,41,71. Brightly, the EU does
not often aim the competition at its end, but mainly
for consumer interests. For Japan, the expression ap-
pears to be that it mainly targets the preservation of
competition, and “thereby,” the consumers’ interests
would be the primary outcomes of such a promotion,
especially in merger regulation.
It seems that the US does not count many goals for
its antitrust law. In history, typically, it intended to
halt trust and economic concentration. Like one of
Japan’s goal, it thus concerned “public interest” and
was not reluctant to recognize “advantages of cheap-
ness or better service which honest, intelligent coop-
eration may bring” at the same time72. One could
find the approach to public interests in cases of Stan-
dard Oil Company of New Jersey et al. v. United
States (1911), United States v. American Tobacco Com-
pany and American Tobacco Company v. United States
(1911), or Brown Shoe Co. v. United States (1962).
However, the school of Chicago’s arguments has
changed theUS approach in the 1970s. Be running far
away from “the progressive or populist political pref-
erences,” the merger regulation as well as the antitrust
law in general, the discussions aimed the sole goal to
the “consumer welfare”73. Consequently, almost all
mergers have been recognized with their efficiencies,
which, as economic logic, benefit consumers at the
end74,75. Thus, the merger review has begun to chal-
lengemergers whose effects have been not cost-saving
1259
Science & Technology Development Journal – Economics - Law andManagement, 5(1):1253-1266
mostly or, in contrast, increasing prices or reducing
market outputs75.
Of course, there have been controversial ideas that
the law needs to consider other criteria such as, for
example, to restrict the big business’s impacts and
send a promotion to the small alongside such pro-
tection of consumers, significantly as affected by the
populist from the 19th century 14,75,76.q Alternatively,
some counterarguments pointed out themassive con-
sumption of consumer welfare standard, which “has
allowed too many mergers to create too much con-
centration in too many markets”77. Ultimately, mar-
ket power has become the most critical concern in
the merger regulation78. When the merger gener-
ates benefits, such as the economic scales’ efficiency,
it could favor consumers. Adversely, the merger law
could detect and prohibit market powers, leading to
monopolization and ten to injure consumers in the
future. The other jurisdictions accordingly have con-
verged with the EU at this point.
Of course, the suspension of theVCLmeans that Viet-
nam finds challenges in mastering the objectives for
its competition law. Under the market power ap-
proach above, the perspectives of Japan and the EU
could contribute significant experience. It implies
that the primary goal of themerger law needs to be the
protection of competition because it, in turn, would
bring other effects to the market as well as consumers
and other market players. Moreover, “thereby,” from
the problems of market power raised by the busi-
ness plan, the merger regulation could anticipate the
lessening competition from various aspects, includ-
ing the decreasing output, releasing innovation, or
other types of dangers on consumers ( 34 Sec.1,43 Part
III.1.B.).
Some scholars in Vietnam also made acquainted with
this prospect. They identified that the law, which is to
protect competition, is to protect themarket andother
economic factors, such as consumers. However, they
included the enterprise and other business operators
into the “other economic factor”79.
Currently, it evidences that Vietnam has approached
the plural interests regarding the goals for the compe-
tition law in general. The scholars proved that compe-
tition law in Vietnam needs to ensure various kinds of
interests3,9. To be familiar with this approach, Viet-
nam needs to have perceived its necessary empha-
sis3,71. Indeed, the construction of regulatory priori-
ties should depend upon the economic foundation80.
Mostly, to absorb this approach, the writing proposes
that Vietnam should pay attention to the “effective
qAs cited fromHans B.Thorelli,The Federal Antitrust Policy, 180-
85, 1955.
competition” experienced from the EU’s aspect. Nat-
urally, the “free and fair competition” has become an-
cient and may lead to some obstacle for the economy
nowadays48,49. As suggested by some Vietnamese
scholars71, the approach to the workable competi-
tion also brings meaningless evidence48,49. Overall,
to achieve the market with effective competition and
priority of consumer welfare could bring the law op-
portunities to restrictions on anti-competitive treat-
ments as what preference of law, the scholars pointed
out3.
To an apparent position of the industrial
policy
The discussions in OECD’s round table in 2009
showed that competition policy in practice could play
as a useful tool for backing to industrial policy’s per-
formance to the stable economy in scale effect. It can
primarily prevent the domestic market from foreign
monopolistic companies’ predatory pricing activities,
make a driving force to new industries, and reforms
of technologies and management for companies’ ac-
complishment80. Interestingly, competition policy
can exist whenever an industrial policy’s positive im-
pacts donot balance enoughmalicious attacks by anti-
competitive reactions81. Therefore, the implementa-
tion of industrial policy should position in a parallel
stage with competition policy, and vice versa, for the
provincial economy’s productivity.
What happened in Japan in history can be an interest-
ing illustration of “obvious success and understand-
ably legitimized government intervention in the econ-
omy”82. Partially, it was of the vigorous enforcement
of industrial policy for the relationship between en-
terprises and investment, which, as Japanese recogni-
tion, was the driving force for its historical hot eco-
nomic development83. In other words, the relaxation
of competition law enforcement played an essential
role in contributing to the Japanese priorities in eco-
nomic reconstruction84. At the time, the JFTC and
MITI had no visible “animosity” after the JAA ad-
justments in 1953. At that time, the legislation be-
came more relaxation reacting to the vivid elasticity
of economic conditions and its relevant industrial pol-
icy84,85. It thereby released the JFTC’s burden in front
of the new competition policy.
In merger control, merger plans face the prohibition
only when they were “may substantially restrain com-
petition,” or when “unfair trade practices have been
employed” in the course of transactions85–87.r The
rThemost important additional rule in the amendment 1953 was
the unfair business practice. Moreover, it should be noted that the
base of “substantially restrain competition” was also enacted for cartel
regulation. It means the cartel per se illegal was deleted.
1260
Science & Technology Development Journal – Economics - Law andManagement, 5(1):1253-1266
critical base of “substantially restrains competition”
was continuously allayed any merger which even sub-
stantially restrains competition in any particular field
of trade was still approved if “it is particularly neces-
sary for the attainment of rationalization.” It resulted
that “the number of violation cases taken by the JFTC
was decreased” in response to the new regulation with
the “co-called preventive or supplementary provisions
concerning restrictive business practices were deleted
from the JAA”88.
It can be said that the motivation for these changes
came from the factual elements in the Japanese econ-
omy and society. The termination of the Japanese –
Korean War with the Peace Treaty in 1951 had sig-
nificantly affected, resulting in the alteration in the
United States’ policy to Japan, which played a vital
role in the Japanese economy at the time36,81,83,87,88.s
Accordingly, such an attitude was towards “allowing
the smoother and easier introduction of foreign capi-
tal and procurement of capital which were very much
needed for Japan to attain economic reconstruction
more rapidly”88.
Of course, these circumstances got down, the role of
industrial policy did not have enough reasons to jus-
tify, the revitalization time of competition law and
policy started, and JAA’s enforcement has become
more and more durable. Instead of the subordinated
tenets among the competition and industrial policy
before the 1990s, like the typical model, the Japanese
competition law nowadays, on the whole, includes
“more clout” and “more powerful, independent, vis-
ible, and active”89. Indeed, it has more demand for
actively enhancing the JAA even though it has already
directed “the value of competition and markets”89.
Alongside tackling competition law goals and pursu-
ing them, if introduced, Vietnam needs a clear insight
into the industrial policy and different policies and le-
gal frameworks for trade and economic development.
It does not mean that Vietnam should eliminate such
policies. However, it is reasonable to suggest a dis-
tinction in which Vietnam could find the appropriate
pathway in incorporation with the competition law
and policy implementation.
There are several pieces of evidence that Vietnam has
much underlined the industrial policy. The remark-
able proof could be the emphasis on the development
of state-owned enterprises90. The Resolution of the
National Congress of the Communist Party of Viet-
nam in 2001 strongly presented its statement to bring
such actors as national champions to enhance their
sMoreover, such a US’ policy was considered as a way to make
Japan as 2bulwark against communist infiltration” in East side of the
world.
domestic and international competitiveness.t More
importantly, the VCL 2018 also reflects this aspect
at Art. 6. Undoubtedly, these orients come at a
price90, especially for the approach that, for the do-
mestic enterprise and economy’s strength, the compe-
tition law’s existence under the several improvements
of market-oriented institutional plays a vital role91.
By contrast, alongside the Vietnamese economy’s im-
mature entrepreneurship, there was even the idea to
deny the competition law’s soon existence, especially
the extreme restriction as to the western model3.
Others argued that Vietnam, which seems to have a
strong demand for government support from the in-
dustrial policy on the initial economic transformation
progress, lacks conditions to enforce the competition
policy12. However, the current debate rejected the
suggestions that other relevant laws could drive the
competition policy, and even different norms such
as, for example, bankrupted dissolutions or market
natural extortion, could turn corporations into effec-
tive ways3. The opponents argued that other laws
find challenges to function as the competition law’s
hands80. As a result, the Vietnamese competition law
was born.
It is not strange when Vietnam still introduces its in-
dustrial policy. Nonetheless, Vietnam has been cur-
rently confusing in the involvement of competition
policy and industrial policy. The previous mention
of the embarrassing targets on competition in tan-
dem with collusion could prove that Vietnam had no
solutions for the peaceful relationship between these
two policies. At least, Vietnam presents no drastically
definitive statement for competition90. For the same
situation where there has been the existing competi-
tion law, Vietnam could learn Japan to select the pri-
ority policy. Yes, it at first need a distinction between
the competition policy and industrial policy.
However, it should be aware that Japan permitted a
justified policy on the industry in history when it did
not provide much consumption of merger remedies.
Undoubtedly, merger remedies could not function to
implement the industrial policy, but it could clear the
desirable mergers that could meet the industrial pol-
icy achievement. In other words, the direction of
mergers could go on even it has not needed more re-
laxation on competition law. More importantly, the
proposed mergers also provide not anti-competitive
effects with appropriate merger remedies.
In practice, Vietnam challenges to obligate the policy
to enhance state-owned companies’ effectiveness; and
tackle the practical aspect that the existing monopoly
t Sec. 4.1 ofThe Strategy for Socio-Economic Development 2001-
2010.
1261
Science & Technology Development Journal – Economics - Law andManagement, 5(1):1253-1266
mostly comes from such a business sector91. It es-
pecially made sense when the state-owned company
was under the Ministry of Trade and Industry, which
has also been authorized to implement the competi-
tion law and policy in Vietnam91. In several circum-
stances, moreover, Vietnam positioned other Min-
istries as dispute settlers in merger cases. For exam-
ple, the Ministry of Information and Communica-
tions has mainly stood in the cases of VNPT and Vi-
ettel and EVN Telecom and Viettel91.
In practice, the context of industrial policy in Viet-
nam has been changing in front of the policy toward
competition. Vietnam recently stated that it aims to
put the public sector and private one into an equal
competing ground under the market-based mecha-
nism(16 Sec. 4.1). However, there is an obstacle
in which there has been misunderstanding about the
state economic sector’s position. For instance, the
present ideas may not identify that the state-owned
economy’s concentration does notmean that Vietnam
aims to create and maintain a monopoly13,91. No-
tably, the accessible insight has been a not clear dis-
tinction of the monopoly’s harmful effects and the in-
effective factual management in state-owned monop-
olist71. These have affected to solve problems on the
relationship between the industrial and competition
policies in Vietnam, particularly for the business sec-
tor of state-owned enterprises. As a result, there has
been a tendency toward industrial policy’s goal even if
there is an existing statement that the implementation
of competition law needs to be more strengthened.
One more time, Vietnam has a remaining pathway in
the VCL 2018. In detail, it also provides that other
ministries shall corporate with the competition au-
thority for “the state management of the competition”
(92 Art. 7.3. ). It should be to remind that, after
the period of the industrial policy’s dominance, Japan
makes JFTC strengthen and independent. Other gov-
ernmental agencies also construct their Divisions of
competition; however, these latter ones play roles in
enhancing competitiveness as partially the industrial
policy targets. Notably, theMITI also has its competi-
tion division, but it does not remain the competition
policy implementation as in history. In brief, Viet-
nam needs to concern the problems when it calls for
other administrative authorities in making competi-
tion law enforcement.
In the final, it should restate the suggestion that Viet-
nam needs an apparent distinction between compe-
tition law and industrial policy. It is even that Viet-
nam could maintain and send its industrial one pref-
erence but in the other active pathway. Under the
perception that competition law does not prohibit the
monopoly, it just supplies the restriction on unlawful
monopolization and monopolist’s treatments93. As a
result, themost vital tool to avoid the conflict between
these two policies, Vietnamneeds to aim its successful
merger enforcement to merge remedy applications as
others74.
CONCLUSION
Thegoals of competition law and policy play a notable
navigator in law enforcement and lead to new rule in-
auguration regimes. However, Vietnam avoids signi-
fying its goals in all two competition law versions, the
VCL 2004 and the recent VCL 2018. There appears
an increasing debate in the academic world in which
competition law goals have been outlined in several
ways.
Indeed, Vietnam has a demand to look at more de-
veloped countries for future policies to harmonize
merger control law. According to some experts,
Japan’s experience can “provide useful lessons” for
developing countries or transitional economies94.u
Moreover, Japan is the leading country participating
in merger deals in Vietnam, which is forecasted to
continue in the coming years95–97. Aside from the
US, Japan, and the EU merger regulations, there are
suitable choices in a comparative study.
Overall, it implies that Vietnam, in its current
progress, could remain the diverse objectives for com-
petition law enforcement. Under the approach to plu-
ral interests, Vietnammust identify ones, or only one,
for priority. From other legal systems’ perspectives, it
sounds that Vietnam should mainly direct the “effec-
tive competition” particularly experienced from the
EU’s aspect. Traditionally, the “free and fair competi-
tion” may be fluently perceived, but it seems too ab-
stract and outdated. The formula of workable com-
petition could supply significant aspects that impact
the enhancement of firms’ competitiveness. Finally,
consumer welfare could have remained for further
achievements. At present, effective competition could
partially target this goal.
Notably, Vietnam needs to maintain the distinction
between competition policy and industrial policy.
These two policies usually run along but for two dif-
ferent goals, which could be a conflict or reciprocity
sometimes. The enforcement of competition law and
policy meets the industrial policy’s demand in the cir-
cumstances does not pronounce that the two regu-
lations always supply familiar outcomes. Of course,
uThe researcher pointed out that “the text of a legal transplant is
only one important consideration. Additionally, the context of com-
petition law and the subtext of changes to the existing norms of eco-
nomic regulation may be just as important to ’importing’ antitrust
law into developing nations or transitional economies.”
1262
Science & Technology Development Journal – Economics - Law andManagement, 5(1):1253-1266
Vietnam could not destroy this for that one. However,
to experience Japanese historical treatments, Vietnam
could find the appropriate direction to peacefully ex-
ecute the industrial policy under supporting condi-
tions of the competition law and policy.
As navigators, the stipulated goals would drive law en-
forcement precisely and powerfully. Not only merger
regulation but also other branches of competition law
need to be motivated by these pilots. Thus, further
studies of competition law goals must expand into
regulations on the cartel, market dominance, et cetera.
Future research on merger control necessarily con-
cerns how the legal goals drive themerger review, par-
ticularly in assessing mergers’ outcomes. In all, prac-
tical enforcement under the pilot of competition law
objectives has a significant demand for deep consid-
eration.
ABBREVIATIONS
DOJThe (US) Department of Justice
ECT The European Economic Community (EEC)
Treaty (the Treaty of Rome in 1957)
EU. The European Union
FTCThe (US) Federal Trade Commission
JAAThe Japanese Antimonopoly Act
MITIThe (Japan)Ministry of International Trade and
Industry
OECDThe Organization for Economic Co-operation
and Development
TFEU The (EU) Treaty on the Functioning of the
Union
USThe United States
VCL Vietnamese competition law
CONFLICTS OF INTEREST
The author declares that she has no conflicts of inter-
est.
AUTHORS’ CONTRIBUTIONS
Truong Trong Hieu has done all works of the article
as a sole author.
REFERENCES
1. Monti G. EC competition law. Cambridge: Cambridge Univer-
sity Press. 2007;p. 527.
2. Huan PH. Các tiêu chí đánh giá tác động hạn chế cạnh tranh
trong tập trung kinh tế [Criteria for evaluating economic con-
centration’s competition restriction]. The Legislative Studies,
Vietnam. 2017;15(343):37–43.
3. Nghia PD. Pháp luật cạnh tranh Việt Nam: Nhu cầu, khả năng
vàmột vài kiến nghị [Competition Law in Vietnam: Demands,
potential application and some suggestions]. State and Law
Review, Vietnam. 2000;11(151):29–35.
4. Minh ND. Một số vấn đề về pháp luật cạnh tranh trong bước
chuyển sang nền kinh tế thị trường ở nước ta [Several is-
sues of competition law on a progress toward the market-
oriented economy in Vietnam]. State and Law Review, Viet-
nam. 2001;1:21–32.
5. Hai BX. Mục tiêu và phạm vi điều chỉnh của Luật cạnh tranh
[The goal and scope of commpetition law]. State and Law Re-
view, Vietnam. 2004;2(190):43–51.
6. Phat NN. Luật so sánh và thực tiễn xây dựng Luật cạnh tranh
của Việt Nam [Comparative law and the fact to establishment
of competition law in Vietnam]. Hanoi Law Review, Vietnam.
2007;4:43–48.
7. Thanh DV. Cạnh tranh bình đẳng vì sự phát triển [Equitable
competition for development]. The Legislative Studies, Viet-
nam. 2004;6:35–38.
8. Phat NN. Luật Cạnh tranh năm 2018 và việc khắc phục những
bất cập của Luật Cạnh tranh năm 2004 liên quan đến kiểm
soát hạn chế cạnh tranh [Competition Law 2018 and over-
coming inadequacies of the Competition Law 2004 on com-
petition restriction control]. State and Law Review, Vietnam.
2019;6:32–52.
9. Phat NN. Nghiên cứu pháp luật cạnh tranh trong bối cảnh sửa
đổi Luật cạnh tranh năm2004 [Research of competition law in
the context of the revision of the Competition law2004]. State
and Law Review, Vietnam. 2017;7:48–59.
10. The Communist Party of Vietnam. The Resolution of the 8th
National Congress of the Communist Party of Vietnam. The
National Political Publishing House. 1996;.
11. The Communist Party of Vietnam. The Resolution of the 9th
National Congress of the Communist Party of Vietnam. The
National Political Publishing House. 2001;.
12. HongTTQ. Luật cạnh tranh trên thếgiới vàởViệtNam: Sựhình
thành và những nội dung cơ bản [Competition law over the
world and inVietnam: Formation andBasic contents]. LawSci-
ence Information (Institution of Law Science, Ministry of Jus-
tice). 2017;(3):4–10.
13. Doanh LD. Những vấn đề cơ bản về chính sách cạnh tranh
và pháp luật cạnh tranh [Basic issues of competition law and
policy]. State and Law Review, Vietnam. 2000;11(151):11–22.
14. HaoTD. Pháp luật cạnh tranh trongđiềukiện chuyển sangnền
kinh tế hàng hóa nhiều thành phần theo cơ chế thị trường ở
Việt Namhiện nay [Competition lawon conditions toward the
market-oriented diverse sectoral economy in Vietnam today].
State and Law Review, Vietnam. 2000;11(151):23–28.
15. Phat NN. Độc quyền và xử lý độc quyền [Monopoly
and monopoly control]. State and Law Review, Vietnam.
2004;8:45–48.
16. The Communist Party of Vietnam. The Resolution of the 12th
National Congress of the Communist Party of Vietnam. The
National Political Publishing House. 2016;.
17. Thanh PV. Đánh giá những điểm hạn chế, bất cập và định
hướng cơ bản trong quá trình sửa đổi Luật cạnh tranh [The
limitations and inadequacies’ assessments and basic orienta-
tions for revising the Competition Law]. In: The Conference
Proceeding. Hanoi: Hanoi Law University - FES institution.
2017;p. 223.
18. Jung Y, Chang S. Korea’s Competition Law and Policies in Per-
spective SymposiumonCompetition LawandPolicy inDevel-
oping Countries. Northwestern Journal of International Law&
Business. 2006;26(3):687.
19. Pham A. Development of Competition Law in Vietnam in the
Face of Economic Reforms and Global Integration, The Sym-
posium on Competition Law and Policy in Developing Coun-
tries. Northwestern Journal of International Law & Business.
2006;26(3):547.
20. Quang TH. Cơ quan quản lý cạnh tranh tại Việt Nam: Thực tiễn
và giải pháp đổi mới nhìn từ mô hình thế giới [Competition
authorities in Vietnam: Practical Reform and Solutions from
the world’s models]. Law Science Information (Institution of
Law Science, Ministry of Justice). 2017;(3):53–63.
21. Nhu Q. Luật Cạnh tranh chỉ là đồ... trang trí [The
competition law is... the ornament]. Phap luat TPHCM on-
line [Internet][cited 2020 Jan 23]. 2017;p. 5–36. Avail-
able from: https://plo.vn/kinh-te/luat-canh-tranh-chi-la-do-
trang-tri-701495.html.
1263
Science & Technology Development Journal – Economics - Law andManagement, 5(1):1253-1266
22. Carl K, Donald FT. Antitrust Policy: An Economic and Legal
Analysis (be written in 1959). In: The Political Economy of the
Sherman Act: The First One Hundred Years, Editor Sullivan E
Thomas. 1 edition. New York: Oxford University Press. 1991;.
23. Herbert JH. The ShermanAct and the Classical Theory of Com-
petition (be written in 1989). In: The Political Economy of the
Sherman Act: The First One Hundred Years, Editor Sullivan E
Thomas. 1 edition. New York: Oxford University Press. 1991;.
24. George JS. TheOrigin of the ShermanAct (bewritten in 1985).
In: The Political Economy of the Sherman Act: The First One
Hundred Years, Editor Sullivan E Thomas. 1 edition. New York:
Oxford University Press. 1991;.
25. Orbach BY. The Antitrust Consumer Welfare Paradox. Journal
of Competition Law and Economics. 2011;7(1):133–164.
26. Robert HB. The antitrust paradox: A policy at war with itself.
1st ed. New York: Basic Books. 1978;p. 484.
27. Robert HB. Legislative Intent and the Policy of the Sherman
Act (be written in 1966). In: The Political Economy of the
Sherman Act: The First One Hundred Years, Editor Sullivan E
Thomas. 1 edition. New York: Oxford University Press. 1991;.
28. Robert HL. Wealth Transfers as the Original and Primary Con-
cern of Antitrust: The Efficiency Interpretation Challenged (be
written in 1982). In: The Political Economyof the ShermanAct:
The First One Hundred Years, Editor Sullivan E Thomas. 1 edi-
tion. New York: Oxford University Press. 1991;.
29. Rudolph JP. The Rule of Reason in Antitrust Law: Property
Logic in Restraint of Competition (be written in 1989). In: The
Political Economy of the Sherman Act: The First One Hundred
Years, Editor Sullivan E Thomas. 1 edition. New York: Oxford
University Press. 1991;.
30. Richard H. What Happened to the Antitrust Movement? (be
written in 1970). In: The Political Economyof the ShermanAct:
The First One Hundred Years, Editor Sullivan E Thomas. 1st ed.
New York, US: Oxford University Press. 1991;.
31. First H. Antitrust in Japan: The Original Intent. Pacific Rim Law
& Policy Journal. 2000;9(1):72.
32. FTC. The Antitrust Laws [Internet]. [cited 2019 Jun 25].
2013;Available from: https://www.ftc.gov/tips-advice/
competition-guidance/guide-antitrust-laws/antitrust-laws.
33. DOJ. TheAntitrustDivision’sMission [Internet]. [cited2020 Jan
29]. 2015;Available from: https://www.justice.gov/atr/mission.
34. DOJ, FTC. The 2010 Horizontal Merger Guidelines. 2010;.
35. Abir D. Monopoly and Merger Regulation in South Korea and
Japan: A Comparative Analysis. Berkeley Journal of Interna-
tional Law. 1996;13(2):143.
36. Brill CA, Carlson BA. US and Japanese Anti-monopoly Policy
and theExtraterritorial Enforcementof Competition Laws. The
International Lawyer. 1999;33(1):75–118.
37. First H. Antitrust enforcement in Japan. Antitrust Law Journal.
1995;64(1):137–182.
38. Wakui M. Antimonopoly Law: Competition Law and Policy in
Japan. 2sd ed. Independently Published. 2018;p. 330.
39. Iyori H. A Comparison of US-Japan Antitrust Law: Looking at
the International Harmonization of Competition Law. Pacific
Rim Law & Policy Journal. 1995;4(1):59–91.
40. The Japanese Anti-monopoly Act. 1947;.
41. Lin P. Competition policy in East Asia: the cases of Japan, the
People’s Republic of China, and Hong Kong. Hong Kong; 2003
Dec p. 44. Report No.: CAPS Working Paper No. 133 (17/02)
CAPS;.
42. Nicolae I. A comparative study between EU and Japanese
Competition Law [JAEM01 Master Thesis]. [Lund, Sweden]:
Lund University. 2015;.
43. The JFTC’s Policies Concerning Procedures of Review of Busi-
ness Combination. 2011;.
44. Monti M. European Competition for the 21st Century. Ford-
ham International Law Journal. 2000;24(5):1602.
45. David G. Law and Competition in Twentieth-Century Europe:
Protecting Prometheus. Oxford, New York: Oxford University
Press. 2003;p. 504.
46. Vallindas G. New Directions in EC Competition Policy:
The Case of Merger Control. European Law Journal.
2006;12(5):636–660.
47. Gerbrandy A. Rethinking Competition Law within the Eu-
ropean Economic Constitution. Journal of Common Market
Studies. 2019;57(1):127–142.
48. Whish R, Bailey D. Competition Law. 8th edition. Oxford,
United Kingdom: Oxford University Press. 2015;p. 1071.
49. Jones A, Sufrin B. EU Competition Law: Text, Cases, andMate-
rials. Sixth Edition. Oxford, New York: Oxford University Press
(Text, Cases, and Materials). 2016;p. 1273.
50. Dunne N. Competition Law and Economic Regulation: Mak-
ing and Managing Markets. 1st ed. London: Cambridge Uni-
versity Press. 2015;.
51. The Treaty of Rome 1957. 1957;.
52. The Treaty on European Union 1992. 1992;p. 34.
53. The Treaty on the Functioning of the European Union 2007.
2007;.
54. Council Regulation (EEC) No 4064/89 on the Control of Con-
centration between Undertakings. Vol. No 4064/ 89. Official
Journal of the European Union. 1989;.
55. Council Regulation (EC) No 139/2004 on the Control of Con-
centration between Undertakings. Vol. No 139/2004. Official
Journal of the European Union. 2004;.
56. Levy N. EU Merger Control: From Birth to Adolescence. World
Competition. 2003;26(2):195–218.
57. Christiansen A. The “more economic approach” in EU merger
control. CESifo Forum. 2006;7(1):34–39.
58. Vasconcelos H. Efficiency Gains and Structural Remedies
in Merger Control. The Journal of Industrial Economics.
2010;(4):742–766.
59. Carles EM, Comp D. EU merger control: How to remove anti-
competitive effects? The 5th Global Merger Control Confer-
ence; Paris, France. 2017;.
60. Lowe P. The Design of Competition Policy Institutions for the
21st Century: The Experience of the European Commission
and DG Competition. Competition Policy Newsletter. 2008;3.
61. EU. Departments and executive agencies [Internet]. Euro-
pean Commission - European Commission. [cited 2020 Feb
21];Available from: https://ec.europa.eu/info/departments_en.
62. Mario M. The Future for Competition Policy in the European
Union. Commission Press Release SPEECH/01/340 presented
at: Merger control: Issues highlighted in the context of the
GE/Honeywell Merger; London. . 2001;.
63. Esteva MC. Innovation in EU merger control. The 66th ABA
Section of Antitrust Law Spring Meeting; Washington. . 2018;.
64. The EU’s Guidelines on the assessment of non-horizontal
merger. Vol. 2008/C 265/07. Official Journal of the European
Union. 2008;.
65. Sauter W. Squaring EU Competition Law and Industrial Policy:
The Case of Broadband. Report No.: DP 2013-021. 2013;.
66. The EU’s Guidelines on the assessment of horizontal merger.
Vol. 2004/C 31/03. Official Journal of the European Union. .
2004;.
67. Johannes L. Competition and Consumers. The Speech of
Director-General for Competition, EuropeanCommission pre-
sented at: EEA 25 years conference; Brussels. 2019;.
68. Richard AP. The Chicago School of Antitrust Analysis (be writ-
ten in 1979). In: The Political Economy of the Sherman Act:
The First One Hundred Years, Editor Sullivan E Thomas. 1 edi-
tion. New York: Oxford University Press. . 1991;.
69. VNMOIT. Bản thuyếtminh chi tiết dự thảo Luật cạnh tranh sửa
đổi [Detailed Notes Of The draft of the Revised Competition
Law]. VN MOIT. 2017;.
70. VN MOIT. Đánh giá tác động dự án Luật cạnh tranh sửa đổi
[Assessment of the revised Competition Law project’s im-
pacts]. (The included profile of the Vietnamese competition
law amendment) . Hanoi. 2017;.
71. Dao NB. Lựa chọn chính sách cạnh tranh trong bối cảnh hội
nhập kinh tế hiệnnay [Selecting competitionpolicy under the
prospect of economicharmony]. The Legislative Studies, Viet-
nam. 2016;11(315):43–50.
1264
Science & Technology Development Journal – Economics - Law andManagement, 5(1):1253-1266
72. Sher SA. Closed But Not Forgotten: Government Review of
Consummated Mergers Under Section 7 of the Clayton Act.
Santa Clara Law Review. 2004;45(1):41–98.
73. Sawyer LP. US Antitrust Law and Policy in Historical Perspec-
tive. Harvard Business School Working Paper. 2019;19:110–
137.
74. DOJ Antitrust Division. Antitrust Division Policy Guide to
Merger Remedies, 2011. 2011;.
75. HovenkampH. ProphylacticMerger Policy. Hastings Law Jour-
nal. 2018;70(43):46–74.
76. Ryan Y, Wayne C. The Case against Antitrust Law: Ten Areas
Where Antitrust Policy CanMove on from the Smokestack Era.
2019;.
77. Steuer R. Incipiency. Loyola Consumer Law Review.
2019;31(2):155–174.
78. Elzinga KG, Howell VM. Geographic Market Definition in the
Merger Guidelines: A Retrospective Analysis. Review of Indus-
trial Organization. 2018;53(3):453–475.
79. Hue DD, Huyen NH. Những vấn đề lý luận cơ bản của Luật
cạnh tranh [Basic regimes for competition law]. State and Law
Review, Vietnam. 2004;9:58–71.
80. Uc DT. Cạnh tranh và pháp luật cạnh tranh Việt nam hiện nay
[Competition and Competition Law in Vietnam today]. State
and Law Review, Vietnam. 2000;11(151):3–10.
81. OECD. Policy Roundtables on Competition policy Industrial
policy and national champions 2009. OECD. 2009;.
82. Schwindt R, McDaniels D. Competition Policy, Capacity Build-
ing, and Selective Adaptation: Lessons from the Japanese Ex-
perience. Washington University Global Studies Law Review.
2008;7(1):53.
83. Sakoh K. Industrial policy: The super myth of Japan’s super
success. Washington, DC: Asian Studies Center. (Asian Studies
Center Backgrounder). 1983;.
84. Seita AY, Tamura J. The Historical Background of Japan’s
Antimonopoly Law. University of Illinois Law Review.
1994;1994:73.
85. Matsushita M. International Trade and Competition Law in
Japan. New York: Oxford University Press. (Modern Japanese
law series). . 1993;p. 352.
86. InoueA. Antitrust Enforcement in Japan: History, Rhetoric and
Law of the Antimonopoly Act. Japan: Dai Ichi Hoki Co., Ltd.
2012;.
87. Murakami M. The Japanese Antimonopoly Act (Nihon no
Dokusen kinshihō). Japan: Tōkyō: Shōji Hōmu. (Commercial
Law). 2003;331.
88. Iyori H. Antimonopoly legislation in Japan. New York: Federal
Legal Publications. 1969;.
89. First H, Shiraishi T. Concentrated Power: The Paradox of An-
titrust in Japan. United States. Report No.: New York Univer-
sity Law and Economics Working Paper 11. 2005;p. 42.
90. Vinh LT. Tư duy phát triển và vấn đề thực thi Luật cạnh tranh
tại Việt nam [Development thinking and issues of compe-
tition law enforcement in Vietnam]. The Legislative Studies.
2010;15(176):42–47.
91. Hau DV. Tìm lời giải cho bài toán về độc quyền và cạnh tranh
[Finding solutions for questions of monopoly and competi-
tion]. The Legislative Studies, Vietnam. 2014;7(263):37–41.
92. The Vietnamese Competition Law 2018. Vol. 23/2018/QH14.
2018;.
93. Phat NN. Các khía cạnh pháp lý về tập trung kinh tế và vai
trò của cơ quan quản lý cạnh tranh [Several aspects of eco-
nomic concentration and the role of competition authority].
Legal Science Journal, Vietnam. 2007;4:14–20.
94. Mehra SK. Same Plant, Different Soil: Japan’s New Merger
Guidelines Symposium on Competition Law and Policy in
Developing Countries. Northwestern Journal of International
Law & Business. 2006;26(3 Spring):515–526.
95. MAF Research, CMAC. Thị trường M&A Việt Nam 2018-2019:
Thay đổi để bứt phá [The M&A Market in Vietnam in 2018-
2019: Going for Breakthrough]. M&A Vietnam 2019: An over-
all. Vietnam; 72-82. (VietnamM&A Outlook 2019);.
96. Stoxplus. VietnamM&A Report 2013 [Báo cáo triển vọngM&A
Việt Nam 2013]. 2013;(3):38.
97. Vietnam M&A Forum. Report on Merger in Vietnam in 2013
and prospects of 2014-2018: The SecondWave [Báo cáo hoạt
độngM&AViệt Nam2013 và triển vọng 2014 - 2018: Làn sóng
thứ hai]. 2014;p. 42.
1265
Tạp chí Phát triển Khoa học và Công nghệ - Kinh tế-Luật và Quản lý, 5(1):1253-1266
Open Access Full Text Article Review
Trường Đại học Kinh tế -
Luật,ĐHQG-HCM, Việt Nam
Liên hệ
Trương Trọng Hiểu, Trường Đại học
Kinh tế -Luật,ĐHQG-HCM, Việt Nam
Email: hieutt@uel.edu.vn
Lịch sử
DOI : 10.32508/stdjelm.v5i1.684
Copyright
© VNU-HCM Press. This is an open-
access article distributed under the
terms of the Creative Commons
Attribution 4.0 International license.
Nghiên cứu so sánh vềmục tiêu của luật cạnh tranh với trường hợp
kiểm soát sáp nhập và các khuyến nghị cho Việt Nam
Trương Trọng Hiểu*
Use your smartphone to scan this
QR code and download this article
TÓM TẮT
Mục tiêu của luật và chính sách cạnh tranh đóng vai trò định hướng cho quán trình thực thi lẫn xây
dựng pháp luật. Dù vậy, Việt Nam đã hai lần bỏ qua việc xác định mục tiêu này khi thông qua Luật
cạnh tranh năm 2004 và 2018. Kiểm soát sáp nhập trên thực tế vì vậy cũng khá lúng túng. Tiếp
nối những tranh luận học thuật lâu nay, bài viết mở ra hướng tiếp cận so sánh với các nền pháp
lý khác. Không phải pháp luật cạnh tranh sớm nhất châu Á là Nhật Bản hay nền pháp luật lớn và
mới là Châu Âu mà luật chống độc quyền Hoa Kỳ đóng vai trò đưa ra hướng tiếp cận cơ bản cho
vấn đề này. Kinh nghiệm các nước cho thấy, Việt Nam có thể duy trình mô hình đa mục tiêu cùng
với việc nhấn mạnh nhóm lợi ích ưu tiên cho luật cạnh tranh. Bỏ qua tiếp cận về cạnh tranh tự do
và bình đẳng hay cạnh tranh khả thi, phân tích hướng đến cạnh tranh hiệu quả dựa trên tiếp cận
chính yếu của châu Âu. Đặc biệt, quá trình thực thi chỉ thật sự hiệu quả khi các chính sách thúc đẩy
cạnh tranh khác được định vị một cách rõ ràng. Tuy nhiên, chính sách công nghiệp, dù có kết nối
quan trọng với chính sách cạnh tranh, không phải sẽ luôn hỗ trợ cho quá trình thực thi luật cạnh
tranh. Kinh nghiệm lịch sử của Nhật Bản sẽ giới thiệu định hướng phù hợp trong xử lý mối quan
hệ phức tạp giữa hai chính sách vừa có sự xung đột vừa có tính tương hỗ này. Đây là những gợi ý
góp phần cho việc pháp điển hóa pháp luật cạnh tranh ở Việt Nam.
Từ khóa: Luật cạnh tranh, chính sách cạnh tranh, chính sách công nghiệp, mục tiêu, kiểm soát
sáp nhập
Cite this article : Hiểu T T. Nghiên cứu so sánh về mục tiêu của luật cạnh tranh với trường hợp kiểm
soát sáp nhập và các khuyến nghị cho Việt Nam. Sci. Tech. Dev. J. - Eco. Law Manag.; 5(1):1253-1266.
1266
History
Nhận bài: 11/8/2020
Chấp nhận: 10/11/2020
Xuất bản: 13/2/2021
Các file đính kèm theo tài liệu này:
- a_comparative_study_on_goals_of_competition_law_with_the_cas.pdf