Access to land has for a long time been advocated as a strategy to reduce rural poverty (Warriner 1969; Thiesenheusen, 1989, Dorner, 1992). This study examines the potential of land in reducing poverty in rural Vietnam, and carefully taking into account the specific conditions under which land is used by households. In this thesis, I use parametric approaches to estimate household welfare index with data from Vietnam Living Standard Survey 2002. Household welfare equation is regressed on a set of variables, which are annual agricultural land, labor force, education attainment, region and household characteristics and dummies.
Based on data from VLSS 2002, the main findings are:
In general, I find that the marginal welfare value of land is quite high. An increase of 1 hectare will increase annually income by 2,700,000 VND, however there is a wide range of difference in return to land among regions. An increase in hectare annual cropland, for example, increased by 1,948 VND a year in RRD and the same in SCC. This value is quite higher in MKD by 2,478 thousands but the marginal value reach highest in SE by 5,981 thousands a year, while there is a cost in 920 and 2,076 thousands VND a year in NW and NCC respectively.
Education is an important factor contributes to household welfare. a marginal increase in the household head’s education level raises welfare by 2,498 thousand VND/year if the head finished primary level and reach up to 14,929 thousands if the heads have education attainment from vocational program, colleague and university or higher.
In my thesis, I also point out some other specific conditions under which land is used by household.
45 trang |
Chia sẻ: aloso | Lượt xem: 1837 | Lượt tải: 1
Bạn đang xem trước 20 trang tài liệu Determinants of poverty reduction potential of land in rural vietnam, để xem tài liệu hoàn chỉnh bạn click vào nút DOWNLOAD ở trên
d facilitate the process of land allocation and registration by outlining procedures and designating responsibilities, and added two new land rights, including the right to use land (including rented land) as capital for joint ventures. The revisions also set out the circumstances for allowing land related changes, and procedures for registration of changes. As might reasonably be expected, land use rights are not free of legislative requirements and constraints. As noted by the East Asia Analytical Unit (1997, p. 27) the ability to transfer, lease, exchange, mortgage or inherit land use rights “varies between different categories of land, landholders and land use rights. Transactions are subject to official approval case by case”. Land related changes that are officially required to be registered with the local authorities include: changing the land use purposes stated in the certificate, re-shaping land plots, changing the land tenure right, using land as a mortgage at banks for borrowings, altering the land use duration, and sub-leasing land. Registration can only be made after the changes are “permitted by the People’s Committee of the competent level and effected in accordance with current regulations” (Circular No. 346/1998/TT-TCDC, 1998, p. 87). Registration of land-related changes incurs a fee. Further revisions in 1999 addressed complaints about the lack of procedures for “implementation” of land use rights (for example: The World Bank in Vietnam, 1998, p. 36). Decree No 17/1999/ND-CP (1999) set out the conditions and procedures for exchange, transfer, lease, inheritance and mortgage of land use rights. The conditions and procedure for land use rights exchange appear straightforward. Exchange of land may occur if “it is convenient for production and livelihood” and “the land must be used for the right purposes and within the term set by the State when the land is assigned” (Decree No 17/1999/ND-CP,1999, p. 15). Conditions for the transfer and lease of land appear stricter, especially for wet rice land (paddy). Households (or individuals) can only transfer land use rights if they move to other places of residence to live or take up production or business activities, change to other occupations or have no capacity to work. The land use right can only be transferred to households or individuals who have the demand to use the land and have no land or a land area less than the land limit. If the transferred land is wet rice land, then the land use right can only be transferred to a household or individual “directly involved in agricultural production” (Decree No 17/1999/ND-CP, 1999, p. 16). Transfer of a land use right involves payment of a tax on the transfer by the transferor, and payment of a registration fee by the transferee. Likewise, conditions apply for the leasing of land use rights. Households can make their land use rights available for lease if the family is in poverty, if they have taken up other occupations or if they lack capacity to work the land. Generally, land is only able to be leased for 3 years, except for “particularly difficult cases as certified by the commune/ ward/township People’s Committee”, and then the lease can be up to 10 years (Decree No 17/1999/ND-CP, 1999, p. 17). Subleasing of land is allowed, but only if the lease money has been paid in advance and the duration of the lease has at least 5 years still to run. Rental and land transfer values do not reflect true market prices, but rather are determined within a pricing framework set by the Central Government, with the actual prices fixed by the provincial or municipal authorities.
Land limits are not rigidly enforced in all areas – especially when there is unused land, but limits hold in the heavily populated delta areas. Although, theoretically, households cannot be transferred land use rights in excess of the land limit, provision is made for households to be able to work land in excess of the limit. Land transferred in excess of the limit must be leased from the State. Lease money is not always charged however, especially for land not considered highly productive (for example, “barren hills” in upland areas). The process of land reform in Vietnam is on going, and another revision to the Land Law has recently been passed by the National Assembly and took effect in October 2001. Considerable pressure is being exerted on the government in relation to the completion of allocation and registration of land use rights, issues related to compensation and the desirability of stable and long-term tenure (for example: Vietnam News, 2000b; Mai, 2001). There is also ongoing debate about the appropriate length of tenure, ceiling levels for land holdings and restrictions on the transfer and use of land.
The process of land allocation
Approximately 80 percent of the populations of some 80 million people live in rural areas and there are over 11 million household farms in Vietnam (GSO 2002). Farm sizes vary throughout the country, but they are typically small. The average size of farms in the Mekong Delta is 1.2 hectares, and this is considerably larger than average farm sizes in the Red River Delta is 0.28 hectares (GSO 2003). The allocation of land use rights is officially undertaken by the General Department for Land Administration, with certificates of title for agricultural land issued by the District People’s Councils. In practice however, the State allocates land use rights through People's Committees at the district and commune level (East Asia Analytical Unit, 1997; The World Bank in Vietnam, 1998). The October 2001 revisions to the Land Law have given local authorities more power to deal with matters such as allocation and leasing of land, and the issuing of land use right certificates.
Since 1993, the process of land allocation in rural areas has been proceeding steadily, along with the necessary mapping that precedes allocation and certification, although a number of problems have arisen with the allocation of forest land (The World Bank in Vietnam, 1998, pp. 35-36): “Directive 10-1998/CT-TTg (20/2/98) claims that 60% of households with rights to 65% of agricultural land have been issued certificates of title. … Only 9.8% of forest land (of which only 1% is natural forest) has been allocated. Local authorities are having to grapple with the complex issues involved in marrying the terms of the 1993 Land Law with customary land-use patterns and rights. The scope for disputes is large since customary owners may vigorously contest the allocation of individual rights.” The allocation process varies between districts, although equity between households was a primary consideration in the land allocation, with consideration being given both to land quality and the number of people, or more specifically labors equivalents, in a household. Consequently, the amount of land allocated varied between households and this land was typically split into a number of plots of varying land quality. The World Bank in Vietnam (1998, p. 10) says “on average, farms in the Red River Delta comprise eight or nine noncontiguous plots often no largerthan 200 to 500 square meters each”. Likewise, Chung (1994, p. 4) reports that in the Red River Delta “households held three to ten plots of farm land scattered in different locations”. In mountainous areas, the number of plots allocated to households tended to be even greater, as the land quality was extremely variable. In the South of Vietnam, the degree of land fragmentation is not so pronounced, with many farmers in the Mekong Delta having only one plot. Be (2000b) suggests that in the South, farmers were “less concerned” with equitable distribution and negotiations took place at District Committee level to “balance” the size of allocations giving consideration to the varying quality of land, and farmers were then allocated larger consolidated parcels. Land allocation to households in the south of Vietnam was also more likely to be based on earlier allocations made during the land reforms of 1975.
Typically, not all land within a commune was allocated. A proportion of land was kept (usually between 5 and 10 percent) “to defray public expenses or readjust land allocation periodically to demographic changes such as family members returning from military service” (Chung, 1994, p.4). Other land such as ponds, lakes and garden areas which are difficult to divide, were often also left unallocated, and then assigned to individual households on the basis of competitive bidding.
Land use in Vietnam
Under the Vietnamese Constitution, land is the property of the people as a whole and the State administers it on their behalf. Since land is 'owned' by the people as a whole, it is not possible for individuals (or corporations) to own land, although they (and foreigners) can own and transfer structures such as houses built on land. However, Vietnamese (but not foreign) individuals, households and organizations can hold and transfer rights to use land. Recent changes to the Land Law made in October 2001 will make it possible for some categories of overseas Vietnamese (Viet Kieu) to hold land use rights. Vietnam has a large population and limited land and, like other countries with high population to land ratio, the value of land is high, and use rights are very important. These rights are crucial to improved private sector development but there are ideological issues that remain important (Fforde, 1995; East Asia Analytical Unit, 1997; AusAID, 2001). Fforde (1995) talks of the difference between Western and Vietnamese understanding of the concepts of public and private land. ‘Private’ land has always been “land over which the local community had considerable residual rights” (p. 93). Hence Fforde (1995, p. 93) argues that “In practice, it is very hard to imagine that various implications of a western concept of private property in land would be accepted – for example, that rice land offered as collateral on a loan by a family should be taken upon foreclosure without the village’s permission.”
Other ideological issues relate to the use of land. Land use should be complete (day du), that is, all land should be used; and reasonable, that is, the land should be farmed efficiently with appropriate crops and rotations and attention paid to maintaining the fertility of the land (Tien, 2000b). In practice, this is determined by restrictions on land use that are specified on the certificate of land use rights. There are conflicting views about to what extent the use of land should be the province of the individual or controlled by the State. However, the centrality of state land management to government policies is still paramount (AusAID, 2001). For example, the Hanoi People’s Committee confiscated over 50 hectares of “illegally used” land in late 2001 and early 2002 (Vietnam News, 2002a). These concerns on the use of land are linked closely to issues of rice policy and food security. Shortages of food were commonplace in the mid- 1980s and that is not so long ago. In some districts control over production in still exerted by the State, particularly with regard to rice production (The World Bank in Vietnam, 1998). Production targets are set at a local level in response to government directives and individual households may have to grow crops as directed. Some 4 million hectares of land in Vietnam is still ‘required’ to grow rice, although this represents a decrease of 0.2 million hectares on land previously set aside for rice production (Vietnam News, 2000c).
Table 1 - Major annual crops grown in Vietnam, 1995-2000
Year
Area of each crop as a percentage of total area under all annual crops
Food crops
Annual industrial crops
Rice
Maize
Sweet
potato
Cassava
Sugarcane
Peanut
Soy-bean
1995
73.3
6.0
3.3
3.0
2.4
2.8
1.3
1996
73.8
6.5
3.2
2.9
2.5
2.8
1.2
1997
73.3
6.8
2.8
2.6
2.7
2.6
1.1
1998
73.5
6.5
2.5
2.4
2.8
2.7
1.3
1999
73.1
6.6
2.6
2.2
3.3
2.4
1.2
2000a
73.3
6.8
2.5
2.2
2.9
2.3
1.2
Note: a - Figures for 2000 are preliminary
Source: Adapted from data reported by GSO (2001).
Percentage land areas planted to some major annual food and industrial crops are given in Table 1. The percentage area planted to rice appears quite stable and kept at quite high ratio for long time, while there has been some increase in the percentage area planted to sugarcane and maize and some decrease in the percentage area planted to sweet potato and cassava (both comparatively low value food crops).
POVERTY IN VIETNAM
Overall Poverty in Vietnam
Table 2 shows that Doi Moi also resulted in an impressive reduction of poverty in Vietnam. It is estimated that before 1986 the national poverty in Vietnam ranged between 74 and 78% (Dollar and Litvack 1998). No matter what poverty measure is selected, all figures indicate that poverty incidence has more than halved in only one decade after the implementation of economic reforms. Indicators in the Table 2 also show that the percentage of the population living below the poverty line declined from over 70 per cent at the end of 1980s to 58 percent in 1993, reducing to 37 per cent in 1998, and kept at 29 per cent in 2002. The proportion of the food-poor decreased from 25 per cent in 1993 to 15 per cent in 1998 and 11 per cent in 2002.
Table 2: Indicators of poverty in Vietnam 1990-2002
INDICATORS ON POVERTY AND INEQUALITY (IN %)
1990
1993
1998
2002
National poverty rate (GSO)
70
58.1
37.4
28.9
Food poverty rate (GSO)
Na
24.9
15.0
10.9
Poverty gap (GSO)
Na
18.5
9.5
6.9
Poverty gap squared (GSO)
Na
8.3
3.6
2.6
Sources: Worldbank (2003), Steering Committee of CPRGS (2003) and MPI
Poverty line of GSO/World Bank Concept = 2100 kl/person/day = 1,916 thousands VND/person/year (price in 2002)
Dimensions of poverty in Vietnam
As already presented above, Vietnam’s economic growth over the past decades was associated with a remarkably strong overall reduction of poverty incidences. However, the household survey data also point to significant changes in the rates of poverty reduction once they are disaggregated into the most relevant dimensions. I deliver a more detail information of the spatial dimensions of poverty (see Table 3).
Table 3: Spatial dimensions of poverty and inequality in Vietnam
POVERTY RATES (HEADCOUNT INDEX %)
SHARE OF POPULATION
(IN %)
YEARS
1993
1998
2002
1993
1998
2002
National dimensions
58. 1
37.4
28.9
100
100
100
Regional dimension
Northern Uplands
81.5
64.2
43.9
15.6
18
15
+ North East
86.1
62
38.4
- -
- -
12
+ North West
81.0
73.4
68.0
- -
- -
3
Red River Delta
62.7
29.3
22.4
21.6
20
22
North Central Coast
74.5
48.1
43.9
12.8
14
13
South Central Coast
47.2
34.5
25.2
12.6
11
8
Central Highlands
70.0
52.4
51.8
3.2
4
6
South East
37.0
12.2
10.6
12.6
13
15
Mekong Delta
47.1
36.9
23.4
22.4
21
21
Area dimension
Urban areas
25.1
9.2
6.6
19.9
20.9
23.23
Rural areas
66.4
45.5
35.6
80.1
79.1
76.77
Source: World bank (2003) and GSO. Regions are defined as in 2002.
As in the table 3 reveals, some regions like South East and Mekong Delta and South Central Coast had lower incidences of poverty than the national average throughout all periods. Red River Delta joined this group in the second phase of growth. North Central Coast, North West and North East and Central Highlands in the south are characterized by incidences of poverty higher than the national average in all periods. Regional poverty incidences are closely related to area poverty rates, since the regions with disproportional reduction in poverty are those with a higher share of urban areas, whereas Central Highlands and North West are mainly rural regions. The figures show that poverty is still considerable higher among rural households where are the overwhelming majority in Vietnam.
Table 4: Ethnic and gender dimensions of poverty in Vietnam
POVERTY RATES (HEADCOUNT INDEX IN %)
SHARE OF POPULATION (IN %)
YEARS
1993
1998
2002
1993
1998
2002
Ethnic dimension
Kinh and Chinese
53.9
31.1
23.1
86.9
85.3
84.2
Ethnic minorities
86.4
75.2
69.3
13.1
14.7
15.8
Gender dimension
Male-headed
households
61
40
31
77.5
78.4
77.58
Female-headed
households
48
28
20
22.5
21.6
22.42
Source: Worldbank (2003), Glewwe et al. (2002)
Table 4 shows the ethnic and gender dimensions of poverty in Vietnam. Both are strongly related to the spatial dimension. Vietnam’s ethnic minorities live in the less populated rural regions and account for the increasing share of these regions in the contribution to overall poverty. Across all regions the data reveal that ethnic minorities did not only enjoy a much smaller reduction of absolute poverty.
The gender dimension of Vietnam’s poverty profile with female-headed households showing less poverty then male-headed households. However, the gender of the household head is only a very rough indicator of differences in well being between men and women. Other indicators will be analyzed below. Female-headed households are usually smaller, are more typical in urban areas and often receive remittances from husbands working elsewhere in the country or overseas (UNDP 2003). Rural female headed households, however, are usually very poor or face a very high vulnerability of falling into poverty (Man Loi 1996, Centre for International Development 2002).
Table 5: Socio-characteristics of Vietnam’s poverty profile
HEADCOUNT INDEX (IN %)
SHARE OF POPULATION %)
1993
1998
2002
1993
1998
2002
1. National Poverty
58.1
37.4
28.9
100.0
100.0
100.0
2. Household size
Small (≤ 3 members)
45.95
16.95
16.69
12.22
12.14
14.83
Medium (3-6 members)
56.86
30.80
25.46
36.36
44.10
50.25
Large (≥ 6 members)
64.72
49.66
41.62
51.43
43.76
34.93
3. Number of children
Number of children ≤ 2
55.92
34.33
24.80
48.69
56.60
57.07
Number of children 2-5
61.57
39.92
33.73
34.81
32.62
32.36
Number of children ≥ 5
66.11
45.64
44.75
16.50
10.79
10.58
4. Occupation of the
household head (*)
White collar
23.6
9.9
29.27
4.6
6.6
6.18
Sales
27.7
13.0
32.84
8.1
9.5
14.80
Agriculture
69.0
48.2
26.85
64.7
61.0
51.73
Production
45.9
26.0
38.55
10.9
11.5
14.20
Other/no work
44.4
27.4
28.83
11.7
11.3
13.10
5. Education of the household head
No schooling
62.6
55.0
37.01
36.1
35.5
31.58
Primary
56.7
42.2
32.24
24.4
23.1
24.52
Low secondary
64.0
38.0
29.32
23.4
22.4
26.47
Upper secondary
44.5
25.1
18.46
4.7
5.2
8.39
Technical worker,
vocational school or
university degree
39.2
14.2
9.97
7.9
13.8
9.04
Source: Worldbank (2003), Glewwe et al. (2002)
2.3 Summary of characteristics of poverty in Vietnam
- The poor in Viet Nam are less educated and less skilled; has more children but less access to l and and credit; spends less on education and has less health insurance coverage; lacks opportunities to earn income and is more vulnerable e to external shocks and risks (Vu Quoc Huy, 2002).
- Poverty incidence was more prevalent and more persistent among ethnic minorities. Ethnic minority households are larger and have more children than the average. The educational attainment of household heads and spouses is lower. Endowments in terms of housing and other assets are also below average. The compounded effect of all these characteristics is such that minority households are substantially poorer. The share of ethnic minorities among the poor is al so increasing steadily, from 20 per cent in 1993 to more than 30 per cent by 2002. The upward trend is even stronger if food poverty is considered instead. The share of ethnic minorities among the food-poor increased from less than 30 percent in 1993 to almost 53 percent in 2002.
- The poor generally have low levels of educational attainment. Although poverty incidence has dropped for every level of educational attainment over the 1990s, the poor have relatively low levels of educational attainment. The highest incidence of poverty (40 percent) is for those w ho have not completed primary school. In 2002, the poor had the lowest literacy rate (less than 90 percent) compared with the non-poor. About one fourth of the poor have not finished primary school. The highest education attainment for another two thirds of them is primary and lower secondary school. Less than 2 percent of them have education higher than upper secondary level (table 5).
- The overwhelming majority of the poor (92 percent) live in rural areas. Poverty is al so very much associated with ethnic minorities living in isolated and mountainous areas such as the Northern Uplands and the Central Highlands.
CHAPTER IV
ESTIMATION RESULTS OF HOUSEHOLD WELFARE
This chapter will use econometric models to explore determinants of the household welfare in rural Vietnam. This chapter has three sections, First section introduces data, second is to introduces variables and the third is results of econometric models. The econometrics model in the household welfare index equation.
DATA
This study is based on Vietnam Living Standards Survey (VLSS) carried out by General Statistic Office (GSO) in 2002.
Survey sample consists of 29532 households with about 132000 people in Vietnam. The survey provides detailed information about employment, income, level of education, and demographic characteristics of household members. The survey also contains valuable information of household such as other income and total land area.
This analysis is confined to household possessing annual crop land as production in rural area nationwide. The final data sample has 9523 household; in 8 regions described as below (table 5)
Table 5: Number of household by region
Region
Number of household
Percentage
Cumulative
Red River Delta
1,786
18.75
18.75
Northeast
1,719
18.05
36.81
Northwest
280
2.94
39.75
North Central Coast
914
9.6
49.34
South Central Coast
910
9.56
58.9
Central Highlands
512
5.38
64.28
Southeast
1,474
15.48
79.75
Mekong Delta
1,928
20.25
100
Total
9523
100
100
Source: Author's calculations based on VLSS 2002
In which 8,254 households or 86.67% belong to Kinh or Chinese group, the rest is 1,269 households in minority ethnic groups.
II. DESCRIPTION OF VARIABLES
1. Dependent variable
Welfare index is defined as income of household in thousand Vietnam Dong per year. Income would include value in cash and in kind payment of Income from wages, salaries of members, Income from renting / leasing agricultural, forestry and aquaculture area; living land and housing, value of scholarship, award. The income also including all from agricultural production activities after deducting expenditures in those agricultural production activities and income from non-farm, non-sivylcuture, non-aquaculture businesses; processing … also included. .All income are adjusted to regionally Consumers’ Price Index (CPI), which obtained from the GSO to receive real wages.
(See Appendix Table-1 provides a detailed description of the variables used in my analysis)
2. Explanatory variables
Land area: I focus on allocated annual agricultural managed and/or used by household. Allocated annual agricultural land is importance in production and total area. It can be irrigated or non-irrigated, (annual agricultural land is for annual crops such as rice or groundnuts.)
Within annual crop-land, the survey identifies five land types:
Allocated land: This is the land allocated to households by the cooperative or productive group under Resolution 10; this accounts for the bulk of the North's crop land;
Long-term use land: Predominant in the South, this differs from allocated land only in that the farmer owes no contracted output (in addition to obligatory taxes for all allocated land) to the cooperative or productive group that allocated the land;
Auctioned land: This refers to a part of the cooperatives' land reserved for bidding by households, with a three to five year tenure depending on the region;
Private land: This consists of land inherited and used by households as a garden area, as well as an area equal to 5% of the commune’s agricultural land that has been handed to households for their private use; this land requires no payment; and
Sharecropped or rented land.
Annual agricultural land can be irrigated or non-irrigated. Unfortunately in VLSS 2002, the information of irrigated and non-irrigated land is not available. We only be provided both in one kind as annual crop land, so that I treat this unique kind as land variable in the thesis. It is expected that larger annual crop land will have higher returns, and its unit is ha.
Education
Education variable is represented by binary variables measuring the completion of some or all of the indicated levels of education. Education is classified into 5 levels that are below primary, primary, lower secondary, upper secondary, and those who have education at level of vocational/ technical, and college and higher degree. Below primary, which are included no education, is treated as the reference group. It is expected that higher levels of education will have bigger returns.
Labor force (number of individuals)
Labor force used in the regression is number of individuals excluding household head in the household that those whose age ranging from 15 to 60 year old for both male and female. Male labor force is in 5 subgroups based on their education attainment, from no education to those who have education at level of vocational/ technical, and college and higher degree. Below primary, which are included no education. It is the same division to female labor force. In my estimation, I include 10 independent variables consists of 5 subgroups for male at five level of education attainments and the same 5 subgroups for female . The results release only 2 subgroups that they have statistically significant, so the rest will be dropped.
Geographical characteristics
Vietnam is characterized by marked geographical variation, some of which reflects different historical evolutions. The country is commonly divided into 8 regions that are relatively homogeneous. I estimate my regressions nationally as well as for the 8 regions for which there was sufficient data, namely the Northwest Uplands, Northeast Upland, the Red River, North Coast, South Central Coast, Central Highlands, Southeast and Mekong Delta. The result shows variable of Central Highland is non-significant and so I drop it out.
Social subsidy
According to data in VLSS 2002, we have non-labor income of household, which is available for income effect on household desire to work. Non-labor income of household is corrected for cross-region price index. It includes remittance and value of in kind presents from overseas; domestic remittance and value of in-kind presents; pension, sickness and one-time job loss allowance; social insurance allowance; other income from social insurance; interest of savings, shares, coupon, loans; income from workshop, machinery, assets, tool...leasing; others (lottery, charity and support from other organizations…). Its unit is in thousand Vietnam Dong per year.
In addition, this study introduces some variables in the welfare household index including ethnicity, local characteristics and income of male and female from self-employed or none.
ESTIMATION RESULTS: The household welfare generating potential of land
Table 6 presents the result of estimation from the household welfare equation. The result shows that the marginal welfare value of land is highly significant. An increase of 1 hectare will increase annually income by 2,700,000 VND. The result of increase of marginal welfare value of land is consistent with results have been reached in Ramo´n Lo´pez and Alberto Valde´s (2002); Frederico Finan, Elisabeth Sadoulet, Alain de Janvry (2002) and Dominique van de Walle and Dileni Gunewardena (2001).
For a better sense of this value, I compare with the poverty line adapted by GSO/WB is 2100 kl/person/day, it is equivalent to 1,916 thousands VND/year (price in 2002) and see that the value of 2,700,000 VND/hectare/year would be a considerable. That is why we say that annual crop land would be a valuable instrument for household in the process of poverty reduction in rural.
Characteristics of household head are associated with large welfare effects. As presented in the table 6 A marginal increase in the household head’s education level raises welfare by 2,498 thousand VND/year (unfortunately my estimation result does give statistically insignificant result of household head without education). Marginal welfare in term of education attainment sharply increase at higher level from 5,996 thousands if education attainment of the head at lower secondary to 8,648 thousands at higher secondary. This welfare would reach up to 14,929 thousands if the heads have education attainment from vocational program, colleague and university or higher, If compare the welfare of subgroup that the head attains only primary level with the highest subgroup we see that it is almost 6 times lower than, the gap is too large and it shows that education attainment would be significant human capital in the process of poverty reduction. There are many researches worldwide and in Vietnam has demonstrated that higher education attainment always raise income for households such as in papers reached by give higher Behrman, J.R. and Knowles, J.C. (1999); Brown, P. and Park, A. (2001); Moock, P.R, H.A Patrinos, and M. Venkatarama (2003); Glewwe, P. and Jacoby, H.G. 2004.
The result presents household that lead by female raise by 1,774 thousands a year. This is consistent with the result presented in the table 4 (Ethnic and gender dimensions of poverty in Vietnam) where poverty incidence was always much lower compare to household lead by male. The value is meaningful, it is about 6.5 times higher than income raised by increase in household age.
Labor force: Labor force used in the regression is number of individuals excluding household head in the household that those whose age ranging from 15 to 60 year old for both male and female. Male labor force is in 5 subgroups based on their education attainment, from no education to those who have education at level of vocational/ technical, and college and higher degree. Below primary, which are included no education. It is the same division to female labor force. In my estimation, I include 10 independent variables consists of 5 subgroups for male at five level of education attainments and the same 5 subgroups for female . The results release only 2 subgroups that they have statistically significant, so the rest will be dropped. The result shows that an additional of an adult male with no education attainment increase welfare by 1,889 thousands VND a year and increase to 1,922 thousands VND if they have primary level. This value is the same with the poverty line used by GSO/WB.
There is a high cost associated with ethnicity as being minority ethnic group by 1,871 thousands VND a year. Dominique van de Walle and Dileni Gunewardena (2000) pointed out that there were larger differences in educational attainments, land assets, household size, infrastructure and other attributes between majority and minority group, above disadvantages of minority group would affect the quality of education and other infrastructure, accessibility to services and information, and off-farm income-earning opportunities. Poverty incidence of minority ethnic group is still so high (table 4).
Table 6 - Estimation of the welfare household index
Arg value
Coefficient
Standard Error
t Statistic
P value
[95% Conf. Interval]
Land assets
3944.787
2699.725
399.910
6.750
0.000
1915.815
3483.635
Social subsidy
2010.723
1.235
0.046
27.100
0.000
1.145
1.324
Head of household characteristics
gender
0.846
1774.459
559.165
3.170
0.002
678.377
2870.541
age
39.638
267.554
14.045
19.050
0.000
240.023
295.085
Ethnicity
0.133
-1871.464
301.564
-6.210
0.000
-2462.593
-1280.334
0< education <6
0.229
2498.406
664.090
3.760
0.000
1196.647
3800.164
6<= education <=9
0.284
5996.175
735.970
8.150
0.000
4553.517
7438.833
9< education <=12
0.093
8648.607
792.435
10.910
0.000
7095.265
10201.950
education >12
0.184
14929.090
743.760
20.070
0.000
13471.170
16387.020
Labor force (number of individual)
Male adults with education = 0
0.174
1888.898
729.769
2.590
0.010
458.394
3319.402
Male adults with 0< education <6
0.203
1921.769
770.308
2.490
0.013
411.801
3431.736
Locality characteristics
Cooperative
0.276
-2500.103
249.538
-10.020
0.000
-2989.251
-2010.955
Male self-employment wage (daily)
5.630
-1.674
1.745
-0.960
0.338
-5.094
1.747
Male no self-employment wage (daily)
26.753
3.983
0.885
4.500
0.000
2.249
5.716
Female self-employment wage (daily)
0.292
-14.192
5.784
-2.450
0.014
-25.529
-2.854
Female no self-employment wage (daily)
6.403
5.088
1.471
3.460
0.001
2.205
7.971
Region
Red River Delta
0.188
1947.667
553.263
3.520
0.000
863.154
3032.180
Northeast
0.181
198.0105
463.113
0.430
0.669
-709.789
1105.810
Northwest
0.029
-920.951
610.888
-1.510
0.132
-2118.423
276.521
North Central Coast
0.096
-2076.030
502.002
-4.140
0.000
-3060.060
-1091.999
South Central Coast
0.096
1877.706
565.241
3.320
0.001
769.712
2985.699
Southeast
0.155
5981.269
582.402
10.270
0.000
4839.637
7122.902
Mekong Delta
0.202
2478.22
517.121
4.790
0.000
1464.553
3491.887
Constant
-4627.079
836.239
-5.530
0.000
-6266.286
-2987.872
Number of observations = 9523
F( 23, 9499) = 137.54
Prob > F = 0.0000
R-squared = 0.4781
Root MSE = 10629
Regression with robust standard errors (White's test for heteroskedasticity)
Source: Author's calculations based on VLSS 2002
In my result, accessing to cooperatives decrease a high value for household, by 2,500 VND a year. This result partly explains the successful process of de-collectivization in Doi Moi, this process has brought significant performance in agricultural production and poverty reduction. However Vietnam is still maintaining the existence of cooperative, but these are facing many difficulties and low efficiency (Vietnam Cooperative Association Report 2004).
Turning to returns to land, they are positive and significant for all regions except for NW and NCC. An increase in hectare annual cropland, for example, increased by 1,948 VND a year in RRD and the same in SCC. This value is quite higher in MKD by 2,478 thousands but the marginal value reach highest in SE by 5,981 thousands a year. While there is a cost in 920 and 2,076 thousands VND a year in NW and NCC respectively.
There is a wide range of difference in return to land among regions since the returns to land will be sensitive to the levels of input use (e.g., labor and capital), technology and environment (e.g., irrigation) in each region, the negative returns in the NU and NCC would suggest that at least one of these components was critically unfavorable there. In fact, the average irrigation ratio of the NU has been much lower than in the RRD (Dollar and Glewwe, 1998; MARD, 2000). According to Kazushi TAKAHASHI (2004) pointed out that the different returns to land caused by the difference in the returns to human capital variables of the RRD are higher than the NU, but lower than the MKD.
SUMMARY OF FINDINGS
In this section, I estimate a household welfare equation to explore the relationship between land and welfare. There are two main findings. First, Agricultural land contribute positive income to household in rural. The marginal value of land would change in all 8 regions that I estimate. Second, the marginal value of land differs according to a household’s complementary assets and contextual setting.
CHAPTER V
CONCLUSION AND POLICY IMPLICATIONS
I. CONCLUSION
Access to land has for a long time been advocated as a strategy to reduce rural poverty (Warriner 1969; Thiesenheusen, 1989, Dorner, 1992). This study examines the potential of land in reducing poverty in rural Vietnam, and carefully taking into account the specific conditions under which land is used by households. In this thesis, I use parametric approaches to estimate household welfare index with data from Vietnam Living Standard Survey 2002. Household welfare equation is regressed on a set of variables, which are annual agricultural land, labor force, education attainment, region and household characteristics and dummies.
Based on data from VLSS 2002, the main findings are:
In general, I find that the marginal welfare value of land is quite high. An increase of 1 hectare will increase annually income by 2,700,000 VND, however there is a wide range of difference in return to land among regions. An increase in hectare annual cropland, for example, increased by 1,948 VND a year in RRD and the same in SCC. This value is quite higher in MKD by 2,478 thousands but the marginal value reach highest in SE by 5,981 thousands a year, while there is a cost in 920 and 2,076 thousands VND a year in NW and NCC respectively.
Education is an important factor contributes to household welfare. a marginal increase in the household head’s education level raises welfare by 2,498 thousand VND/year if the head finished primary level and reach up to 14,929 thousands if the heads have education attainment from vocational program, colleague and university or higher.
In my thesis, I also point out some other specific conditions under which land is used by household..
II. POLICY IMPLICATIONS
Based on findings in my thesis, main policy implications are as follow:
Poverty incidence mainly appears in rural area and land still is a major instrument for household to generate income, so the government should provide favorable conditions for peasants to assess to land. It would will greatly be supported by strengthening the implementation of land legislation, improving the quality of land use planning, developing an appropriate land use tax law, and improving the openness and transparency of the land administration system. Land reform should be closely combined with specific conditions under which land is used by households.
Education would be key factor to positively effect on household welfare in rural. Higher education attainment in subgroups create higher income from land than others especially skilled level, so the government should pay more investment in education, especially in minority ethnic group. The government should consider an assistance strategy about technical and vocational training for people in rural area. These training programs have to actually improve the skills for the needs of agricultural production.
III. SUGGESTION FOR FURTHER STUDY
Some important variables for household welfare index could not be handled in this thesis. First, annual agricultural land should be divided into 2 kinds including non-irrigated and irrigated ones, unfortunately, this division was unavailable in VLSS 2002. Second, the effect of road infrastructure on agricultural production was also not considered. It is evident that better transport infrastructure leads to higher output and lower input prices and creates therefore incentives for higher household welfare. Lastly, health services might affect household welfare. However, its effect is difficult to assess with data of VLSS 2002. Furthermore, household welfare index used here based on household income, it is simple and vulnerable index. Welfare index should be build as a multidivisional complex one.
REFERENCES
AusAID, 2001. Vietnam: Land administration, Working Paper 4, Commonwealth of Australia, Australian Agency for International Development, Canberra.
Behrman, J.R. and Knowles, J.C. (1999), “Household income and child schooling in Vietnam”, The World Bank Economic Review, 13(2), 211-256.
Binswanger, Hans, Deininger, Klaus, Feder, Gershon, 1995. Power, distortions, revolt, and reform in agricultural land relations. In: Behrman, J., Srinivasan, T.N. (Eds.) Handbook of Development Economics, vol. 3B. North- Holland, Amsterdam.
Brown, P. and Park, A. (2001), “Education and poverty in rural China”.
Carter, Michael, Mesbah, Dina, 1993. Can land market reform mitigate the exclusionary aspects of rapid agroexport growth? World Development 21 (7), 1085–1100.
Chung, Do Kim, 1994, “Resurgence of Rural Land Markets after Decollectivization in Vietnam: Empirical Findings and Policy Implications”. Paper presented at the International Workshop on Social Research Methods in Agricultural Systems: Coping with Increasing Resource Competition in Asia, 2-4 November, 1994, Chang Mai, Thailand.
Circular No. 346/1998/TT-TCDC, 1998. “Guiding the Procedures for Land Registration, Compiling Cadastral Dossiers and Granting Land Tenure Certificates”, Official Gazette No. 15, Government of Vietnam, 31st May 1998, pp. 77-85.
Decree No.17/1999/ND-CP, 1999, “On the Procedures for Exchange, Transfer, Lease, Sublease and Inheritance of the Land Use Right as well as for Mortgage of and Capital Contribution with the Land Use Right Value”, Official Gazette, No. 17, Government of Vietnam, 8th May 1999, pp. 13-24.
Deininger, Klaus, Feder, Gershon, 2002. Land institutions and policy: key messages from the policy research report
Dollar, D. and Litvack, J. (1998), Vietnam’s Renovation – A Unique Growth Path, Washington, D.C.
Fforde, A., 1995. Vietnam Economic Commentary and Analysis No. 7, Aduki Pty. Ltd., Canberra.
Finan, F; Sadoulet, E; Janvry A.D (2002); Measuring poverty reduction potential of land in rural Mexico, Journal of Development Economics 77 (2005) 27– 51
Glewwe, P. , Granolati, M. and Zarnan, H. (2002), Who Gained from Vietnam’s Boom in the 1990s, in: Economic Development and Cultural Change, 773-792.
Glewwe, P. and Jacoby, H.G. 2004. “Economic growth and the demand for education: is there a wealth effect?” Journal of Development Economics 74 (2004) 33– 51
GSO, 2000. Statistical Yearbook 1999, Statistical Publishing House, Hanoi.
GSO, 2001, Statistical Yearbook 2000, Statistical Publishing House, Hanoi.
GSO, 2002, Statistical Yearbook 2001, Statistical Publishing House, Hanoi.
GSO, 2003, Statistical Yearbook 2002, Statistical Publishing House, Hanoi.
GSO, 2003, Statistical Yearbook 2003, Statistical Publishing House, Hanoi.
accessed to 23 October, 2005
Hubacek, K; Jeroen, C.J.M. (2002) “The Role of Land in Economic Theory” Interim Report IR-02-037
Jean Claude. R. (2001): “Agricultural Production, Agricultural Land and Rural Poverty in Madagascar”, Latin American and the Caribbean Technical Department, Regional Studies Program. Washington, DC: The World Bank.
Kazushi TAKAHASHI (2202) “Sources of Regional Income Disparity in Rural Vietnam: Oaxaca-Blinder Decomposition”, PRUS Working Paper No. 8, Sussex
Kerkvliet, Benedict J. Tria, 2000. “Governing Agricultural land in Vietnam: an Overview”, An overview paper written for ACIAR Project ANRE 1/97/92 “Impacts of Alternative Policy Options on the Agricultural Sector in Vietnam”, Research School of Pacific and Asian Studies, The Australian National University, November 2000.
Lo´pez, Ramon, Valde´s, Alberto (Eds.) 2000b, Rural poverty in Latin America. St. Martin’s Press, New York.
Pingali, Prabhu L., and Vo-Tong Xuan (1992) ‘Vietnam: Decollectivization and rice productivity growth.’ Economic Development and Cultural Change pp. 697–718
The World Bank in Vietnam, 1998. Vietnam – Advancing Rural Development from Vision to Action, The World Bank, in collaboration with the Government of Vietnam, ADB, UNDP, FAO, and CIDA, and in consultation with international donors and NGOs, Consultative Group Meeting for Vietnam, December 7-8, 1998.
The World Bank in Vietnam, 2000 (a). Vietnam – Attacking Poverty, Vietnam Development Report 2000 (b), Joint Report to the Government of Vietnam-Donor-NGO Poverty Working Group, Consultative Group Meeting for Vietnam, December 14-15, 1999.
The World Bank, 2001. Vietnam Economic Monitor, The World Bank, Vietnam, Autumn 2001.
The World Bank in Vietnam, 2002. Vietnam Development Report 2002: Implementing Reform for Faster Growth and Poverty Reduction, The World Bank in Vietnam, Hanoi, Vietnam.
Thiesenheusen, William, 1989. Searching for agrarian reform in Latin America. Unwin Hyman, Boston.
Thorsnes, P., and D.P. McMillen. (1998). “Land Value and Parcel Size: A Semiparametric Analysis,” Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics, 17:3, 233-244.
Tien, To Dung, 2000. ‘Family farms in Vietnam’, transcript of a presentation made to the ACIAR Project ANRE 1/97/92 team, Hanoi Agricultural University, 24th February 2000. Agricultural University, pers.comm., 29th June 2000.
UNDP, 2000. Annual Report 2000, UNDP Vietnam, Hanoi.
Van de Walle, D. and Gunewardena, D. (2001), Sources of Ethnic Inequality in Viet Nam, in: . Journal of Development Economics, 65, 177-207.
Vietnam News, 2002. “Hanoi confiscates illegally used land”, January 4th 2002.
Vu Manh Loi (1996), Female-Headed Households in Vietnam, University of Washington, Center for Studies in Demography and Ecology, Seattle.
Warriner, Doreen, 1969. Land reform in principle and practice. Clarendon Press, Oxford.
APPENDICES
Table 1: Definition of variables used in regression
Variables
Definition
Dependent variable
Household welfare
Total agricultural production income + Total livestock income + Total income from farm services + Total income from sylviculture + Total income from hunting down, trapping, domesticating forestry animals + Income from aquaculture + Income from non-famr, non-sivylcuture, non-aquaculture businesses; processing…. minus expenditures from these production activites. Household welfare also include from value of scholarship, award + Income from wages, salaries of members + Income from renting / leasing agricultural, forestry and aquacutural area; living land and housing and from other incoming money which is considered as income
Explanatory variables
Land assets
Annual agricutural land, it combines both irrigated and non-irrigated as one
Social subsidy
Remittance and value of in-kind presents from overseas + Domestic remittance and value of in-kind presents + Pension, sickness and one-time job loss allowance + Social Insuarance allowance + Other income from social insurance + Interest of savings, shares, coupon, loans + Income from workshop, machinery, assets, tool … leasing + Others (lotery, charity and support from other organizations ..)
Head of household characteristics
Gender (dummy)
= 0 if male, 1 if female
Age (year)
Education level
Ethnicity (dummy)
= 0 if Kinh or Hoa, =1 if not Kinh or Hoa
Labor force (number of individuals)
Male adults with education = 0
Male adults with 0< education <6
Male adults with 6<= education <=9
Male adults with 9< education <=12
Male adults with education >12
Female adults with education = 0
Female adults with 0< education <6
Female adults with 6<= education <=9
Female adults with 9< education <=12
Female adults with education >12
Social and institutional assets
Access to agriculture cooperative (dummy)
Coop = 1 if yes; otherwise = 0
Locality characteristics
Male agricultrial wage (daily)
Male non-agricultrial wage (daily)
Male self-employed wage (daily)
Female agricultrial wage (daily)
Female non-agricultrial wage (daily)
Female self-employed wage (daily)
Region dummies
=0 if Red River Delta (benchmark)
=1 if Northeast
=2 if Northwest
=3 if North Central Coast
=4 if South Central Coast
=5 if Central Highlands
=6 if Southeast
=7 if Mekong Delta
Mean characteristics of variables
Obs
Mean
Std. Dev
Min
Max
Household welfare
9523
18153.27
14694.26
-2154.92
223455.6
Land assets
5993
3944.787
6472.268
0
140000
Social subsidy
9523
2010.723
5679.258
0
117641.1
Head of household characteristics
gender
9523
0.8461619
0.3608124
0
1
age
9523
39.63793
8.001822
17
60
Ethnicity
9523
0.1332563
0.3398694
0
1
Education = 0
9523
0.2091778
0.4067429
0
1
0< education <6
9523
0.2290245
0.4202271
0
1
6<= education <=9
9523
2840491
0.450984
0
1
9< education <=12
9523
0.0933529
0.2909417
0
1
education >12
9523
0.1843957
0.3878269
0
1
Labor force (number of individuals)
Male adults with education = 0
9523
0.1739998
0.3791292
Male adults with 0< education <6
9523
0.2027722
0.4020854
Male adults with 6<= education <=9
9523
0
0
0
Male adults with 9< education <=12
9523
0
0
0
Male adults with education >12
9523
0
0
0
Female adults with education = 0
9523
0.035178
0.1842391
0
1
Female adults with 0< education <6
9523
0
0
0
Female adults with 6<= education <=9
9523
0
0
0
Female adults with 9< education <=12
9523
0
0
0
Female adults with education >12
9523
0
0
0
Locality characteristics
Cooperative
9523
0.2763835
0.4472322
0
1
Male self-imployment wage
9523
5.630192
42.1485
0
1188.294
Male nonself-imployment wage
9523
26.7531
175.3239
0
4702.248
Female self-imployment wage
9523
0.2916305
9.735414
0
720.8564
Female nonself-imployment wage
9523
6.402541
98.62198
0
3895.906
Region
Red River Delta
9523
0.1875459
0.3903696
0
1
Northeast
9523
0.1805103
0.3846322
0
1
Northwest
9523
0.0294025
0.1689408
0
1
North Central Coast
9523
0.0959782
0.2945768
0
1
South Central Coast
9523
0.0955581
0.2939997
0
1
Central Highlands
9523
0.0537646
0.2255644
0
1
Southeast
9523
0.1547832
0.3617168
0
1
Mekong Delta
9523
0.2024572
0.4018523
0
1
Các file đính kèm theo tài liệu này:
- 11098.doc