Conclusion
The paper measures the ERPT on the basis of VAR. The empirical results point out that
ERPT is incomplete (less than 1 percent); specifically, the pass-through coefficient is −0.05
after 3 months; −0.13 after 6 months; −0.22 after 12 months; and −0.24 after 15 months.
It means that 1 percent increase in the REER (i.e. appreciation) will decrease CPI by
0.05 percent over the next 3 months; by 0.13 percent after 6 months; by 0.22 percent after
12 months; and by 0.24 percent after 15 months. In addition, the variance analysis suggests
that the REER may explain about 5 percent of the change in inflation after 3 months;
22 percent after 6 months; 43 percent after 12 months; and 47 percent after 15 months. This
evidence argues that the REER significantly affects inflation in Vietnam.
Future work: because of the data limitation, this paper has not yet investigated and
compared ERPT in two different periods, which reflects two different exchange rate
regimes: from 2008 to 2015 and from 2016 onward:
(1) From 2008 to 2015, SBV applied the exchange rate mechanism through the average
interbank exchange rate tool and the exchange rate band. Specifically, the average
exchange rate in the interbank market in the previous day was the index basis for
determining the next day’s exchange rate. SBV regulated the trading band in each
period, and it directly intervened in the interbank foreign exchange market to
monitor the daily exchange rate.
(2) From 2016 onward, SBV has applied the exchange rate mechanism through the
central exchange rate tool and the exchange rate band. The central exchange rate is
determined by domestic and foreign factors, such as the average exchange rate in
the interbank foreign currency market; exchange rates in the international market of
some largest trading partner countries’s currencies; and balance on macroeconomic
and monetary policy.
So in the future, research studies could investigate and compare ERPT in two different
exchange rate regimes. By doing this work, they could find the exchange rate regime,
2008‒2015 exchange rate regime or 2016 onward exchange rate regime, that affects inflation
more significantly
12 trang |
Chia sẻ: hachi492 | Ngày: 14/01/2022 | Lượt xem: 219 | Lượt tải: 0
Bạn đang xem nội dung tài liệu Exchange rate pass - through into inflation in Viet Nam: Evidence from var model, để tải tài liệu về máy bạn click vào nút DOWNLOAD ở trên
Exchange rate pass-through into
inflation in Vietnam: evidence
from VAR model
Van Anh Pham
Department of Monetary Policy, State Bank of Vietnam, Hanoi, Vietnam and
Crawford School of Public Policy,
Australian National University, Canberra, Australia
Abstract
Purpose – The purpose of this paper is to examine and analyze the exchange rate pass-through into inflation
(ERPT) in Vietnam.
Design/methodology/approach – The paper examines and analyzes the ERPT in Vietnam by applying
vector autoregression model over the period 2008‒2018.
Findings – The key finding of the research is that from the impulse response results, the transmission of
exchange rate shocks to inflation is significant in Vietnam, and this is incomplete exchange rate pass-through.
Moreover, the evidence from variance decompositions argues that exchange rate is an important factor to
explain the fluctuation of inflation.
Originality/value – In overall, the depreciation or appreciation of exchange rate in Vietnam will considerably
impact inflation.
Keywords Vietnam, Vector autoregression, Exchange rate pass-through into inflation
Paper type Research paper
1. Introduction
After being a member of World Trade Organisation (WTO) in 2007, Vietnam has been deeply
integrated into the global economy. Therefore, the exchange rate that represents the
relationship between Vietnam and the world plays an important role, as well as affects many
macroeconomic factors including inflation. Now, quantitative studies on the exchange rate
pass-through into inflation (ERPT) are scarce in Vietnam, especially during the post-WTO
period. Hence, in this study, the author estimates and analyses the impact of exchange rate on
inflation quantitatively in Vietnam over that time to contribute to existing literature.
Goldberg and Knetter (1997) defined exchange rate pass-through as “the percentage
change in local currency import prices resulting from a one percent change in the exchange
rate between the exporting and importing countries” (p. 1248). However, this definition also
extends to producer prices and consumer prices. According to the authors, there are two
types of exchange rate pass-through: incomplete exchange rate pass-through if exchange
rate pass-through is less than 1 (exchange rate changes by 1 percent and price levels change
by less than 1 percent) and complete exchange rate pass-through if exchange rate
pass-through is equal or greater than 1 (exchange rate changes by 1 percent and price levels
change by 1 percent or greater than 1 percent).
There are some researchstudies on ERPT in different countries. Dornbursch (1987)
studied the US market in the 1980s and proved that in the imperfectly competitive market,
Journal of Economics and
Development
Vol. 21 No. 2, 2019
pp. 144-155
Emerald Publishing Limited
e-ISSN: 2632-5330
p-ISSN: 1859-0020
DOI 10.1108/JED-07-2019-0013
Received 17 July 2019
Revised 4 October 2019
Accepted 8 October 2019
The current issue and full text archive of this journal is available on Emerald Insight at:
www.emeraldinsight.com/1859-0020.htm
JEL Classification — C32, E52, F31
© Van Anh Pham. Published in Journal of Economics and Development. Published by Emerald
Publishing Limited. This article is published under the Creative Commons Attribution (CC BY 4.0) licence.
Anyone may reproduce, distribute, translate and create derivative works of this article ( for both
commercial and non-commercial purposes), subject to full attribution to the original publication and
authors. The full terms of this licence may be seen at
144
JED
21,2
ERPT is not complete and opposite to the ratio between the number of domestic enterprises
and the number of foreign enterprises. In other words, the increase in competitive pressure
faced by the domestic firms leads to a decrease in ERPT. Meanwhile, Taylor (2000) studied
the US market from the 1960s to the 1990s to conclude that ERPT is proportional to the
inflation level. To be more exact in the lasting inflation, enterprises are aware that inflation
fluctuations are not temporary, so they adjust their product prices.
McCarthy (2000) compared countries such as the USA, Belgium, Germany, France, the
Netherlands, the UK, Japan, Sweden and Switzerland over the period 1976‒1998 to confirm
that ERPT in the emerging countries is greater than ERPT in the developed countries.
Moreover, Campa and Goldberg (2005) used data series from 1975 to 2003 for 23 countries in
Organization for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD) to find the following:
ERPT is small in the short term; ERPT is significant in the countries where the exchange
rate is unstable; and important factor affecting ERPT is not macroeconomicvariables, it is
the change of imported goods. Besides, Lian (2006) also studied the impact of the exchange
rate pass-through on three price indices (producer prices, import prices and consumer
prices) over the period 1980‒2007 of 09 OECD countries. The result shows that the exchange
rate pass-through is less than 1, both in the short and long term. In particular, the exchange
rate pass-through into the import prices is the largest, and the exchange rate pass-through
into the consumer prices is the smallest. At the same time, the authors also concluded that
the exchange rate pass-through is always more considerable in small countries
characterized by large scale of imported goods, rigid exchange rate regime, inconsistent
monetary policy and high inflation.
In Vietnam, there are some research studies on ERPT. Specifically, Vo (2009) found
that the exchange rate pass-through is complete after five to seven months since the
exchange rate fluctuates, then it gradually decreases; the exchange rate pass-through into
consumer prices is greater than the exchange rate pass-through into import prices.
Furthermore, Nguyen et al. (2009) also evaluated the exchange rate pass-through. Their
results point out that inflation in the period 2005‒2009 changes by 0.07 percent after two
months when exchange rate changes by 1 percent, and this effect completely disappeares
in the third month.
In general, there are two main approaches to investigate exchange rate pass-through,
namely micro-approach used in studies such as Dornbursch (1987), Krugman (1986) and
Feinberg (1986), and macro-approach used in studies such as Taylor (2000), McCarthy (2000)
and Ito and Sato (2006). Researchers such as Olivei (2002), Otani et al. (2005), Campa and
Goldberg (2005) and Campa et al. (2005) used ordinary least square (OLS) to measure ERPT,
whereas other researchers used vector autoregression model (VAR) to measure ERPT, for
instance McCarthy (2000), Leigh and Rossi (2002), Hahn (2003), Belaish (2003), Faruqee
(2006) and Ito and Sato (2006). According to McCarthy (2000), VAR model is better than OLS
model due to following reasons: VAR model improves limitation of OLS regarding non-
stationary issues, and it identifies the comtemporanous impacts among variables, so
variables affect each other, instead of unique direction impact in OLS model. This paper
follows the macro-approach and uses VAR to evaluate ERPT in Vietnam, during post-WTO
period from 2008 to 2018.
Based on monthly data from 2008M1 to 2018M5, the paper contributes to existing
studies by threefold aspects. First, the paper sets up VAR model with one exogenous
variable (world price of oil) and five endogenous variables (output gap, consumer price
index, broad money, lending interest rate and real effective exchange rate (REER)) to
evaluate ERPT. Second, for the key variable in the model (i.e. exchange rate), the paper
calculates the REER and uses this exchange rate ratio in order to examine the pass-through
level. The reason is that the nominal exchange rate is fixed for a long time and makes little
sense to Vietnam economy. Third, the paper focuses on the post-WTO period of Vietnam,
145
ERPT in
Vietnam
which is now scarce to study ERPT. The results from impulse responses and pass-through
coefficients represent that ERPT in Vietnam is incomplete. In addition, the variance
decomposition analysis of inflation suggests that the REER is an important factor to explain
the fluctuation of inflation. In general, it is likely to say that the REER significantly affects
inflation in Vietnam. It means that the exchange rate policy (i.e. appreciation or depreciation)
plays an important role in influencing macroeconomic factors like inflation in Vietnam.
The rest of this paper is organized as follows: Section 2 mentions that VAR model is used
to identify the exchange rate shocks; Section 3 explains the results of model; Section 4
provides robutsness; and Section 5 presents conclusion and future study.
2. Methodology and data
2.1 Methodology
McCarthy (2000) and Hahn (2003) argued that exchange rate and price level are key
variables to estimate exchange rate pass-through; oil price and output capture impacts of
real side in economy; money aggregate and interest rate capture impacts of money market
side, allowing monetary policy to influence exchange rate pass-through. All variables are
needed in the model of ERPT. Based on arguments of McCarthy (2000) and Hahn (2003), as
well as adjusted to Vietnam economy, the paper conducts the VAR model as follows:
Yt ¼ AYt1þet ;
where Yt comprises one exogenous variable (world price of oil) and five endogenous
variables (IP ‒ output gap, CPI ‒ consumer price index, M2 ‒ broad money, IR ‒ lending
interest rate and REER ‒ REER) at time t; Yt−1 comprises one exogenous variable (world
price of oil) and five endogenous variables (IP, CPI, M2, IR and REER) at time t−1; A is
coefficient matrices; and et is error terms at time t.
Structural shock is identified by Cholesky decomposition, specifically ordering variables.
Thus, variables will respond contemporanously to variables’ shocks that are placed ahead,
and they will not be affected contemporanously by variables’ shocks that are placed behind.
According to Bernanke and Mihov (1998), the non-policy variables such as oil price, output
and price level are placed first, followed by the policy variables such as money aggregate,
interest rate and exchange rate. Therefore, the recursive restriction is imposed as follows:
eOIL
eIP
eCPI
eM2
eIR
eREER
2
666666664
3
777777775
¼
z11 0 0 0 0 0
z21 z22 0 0 0 0
z31 z32 z33 0 0 0
z41 z42 z43 z44 0 0
z51 z52 z53 z54 z55 0
z61 z62 z63 z64 z65 z66
2
666666664
3
777777775
uOIL
uIP
uCPI
uM2
uIR
uREER
2
666666664
3
777777775
:
Hence, the exogenous variable ‒ oil price ‒ is placed first. Oil price shocks could then impact
contemporanously all other endogenous variables, but oil price does not respond to other
variables’ shocks. The next variables that describe the macro-domestic market are output
and price level. Output is only affected by oil price’s shocks contemporanously and does not
respond to price level, money aggregate, interest rate and exchange rate shocks
contemporanously. However, price level is affected by oil price and output shocks
contemporanously and does not respond to money aggregate, interest rate and exchange
rate shocks contemporanously. Following macro-domestic market is monetary market,
which includes money aggregate and interest rate. Broad money variable mentions money
demand function where real money demand depends on the opportunity cost of holding
146
JED
21,2
money and real income. Besides, interest rate variable reflects the monetary policy rule in
which the Central Bank will set up a suitable interest rate, after observing the current
domestic currency velocity in the economy. So broad money is affected by oil price, output
and price level shocks contemporanously and does not respond to interest rate and
exchange rate shocks contemporanously. However, interest rate is affected by oil price,
output, price level and money aggregate shocks contemporanously and does not respond to
exchange rate shocks contemporanously. As a forward-looking asset price, the exchange
rate is ordered last to respond to all variables’ shocks in the system contemporaneously.
2.2 Data
The model comprises one exogenous and five endogenous variables; all variables are
derived from M1:2018 to M5:2018, and they need to be seasonally adjusted (except
financial variables).
Oil price: in the paper, oil price is UK Brent oil price, and it is extracted from Federal
Reserve Bank. Oil price will definitely impact the import price and consumer price; changes
in world price of oil make a considerable influence on the inflation rate in Vietnam.
Industrial output: following the aforenamed studies, monthly industrial production is used
as proxy for output, since there are no monthly statistic data on Gross Domestic Product.
Industrial production data are derived from VietnamGeneral Statistics Office (GSO). Hodrick‒
Prescott filter is used to estimate potential output, based on real industrial production. The
difference between the actual output and the potential output is output gap. This variable does
not need to adjust seasonality, as seasonal effects have been eliminated by Hodrick‒Prescott
technique. Industrial output gap is used in the model to represent aggregate demand pressure.
If other factors are held constant, when real output is more than potential output (positive
output gap), this implies that the demand increases, so inflation starts increasing and vice
versa when real output is less than potential output (negative output gap). This implies that
with the decrease of the demand, there is a decrease in inflation.
Consumer price index: this indicator is taken from GSO in order to measure the inflation. In
Vietnam economy, inflation is characterized by seasonality: inflation increases from December
and starts falling in February due to New Year festival and Lunar New Year festival.
Monetary variables: according to Milton Friedman (1963), inflation is considered as a
monetary phenomenon. This is a policy variable that plays an important role in
macroeconomic stability including inflation, but this can be the main cause of high inflation as
well as other instabilities of macroeconomics. The paper uses the broad money supply M2 and
lending interest rates to represent the demand and supply on the monetary market. The data
are extracted from International Financial Statistics (IFS) and State Bank of Vietnam (SBV).
Exchange rate: SBV publishes official exchange rate, namely average interbank exchange
rate (from 2008 to 2015) or central exchange rate ( from 2016 onwards); however, this nominal
exchange rate seems as anchor. Sometimes it is fixed for a long period, and it does not reflect
the movement of macroeconomics factors. Hence, the paper calculates and uses the REER,
instead of the nominal exchange rate, to evaluate ERPT in Vietnam. REER reflects the value
of domestic currency VND; this ratio accounts to inflation and exchange rate movements of
the largest trading partner countries with Vietnam (USA, EU, China, Japan, Korea, Thailand
and Singapore). The data to calculate REER are derived from GSO, SBV and IFS:
REERj ¼
YN
i¼1
djei;j
di
Wi
;
where N¼ 7 foreign countries including USA, EU, China, Japan, Korea, Thailand and
Singapore; ei,j is the exchange rate between Vietnam and each foreign country; Wj is trade
weight of each foreign country; dj is Vietnam’s CPI; and di is each foreign country’s CPI.
147
ERPT in
Vietnam
Therefore, if REERW100, domestic currency appreciates; if REERo100, domestic
currency depreciates; and if REER¼ 100, domestic currency does not change.
3. Empirical results
3.1 Unit root test
The augmented Dickey‒Fuller (ADF) unit root test is used to examine variable stationarity.
When analyzing time-series data, stationarity absolutely needs to be checked and to be
satisfied. If variables are non-stationary, it leads to spurious regression and unreliable results.
The ADF results show that variables such as broad money M2 and output gap IP are
stationary, whereas others are non-stationary, which makes the system to be non-stationary.
According to Sims et al. (1990) and Fujiwara (2003), even if macro variables are
non-stationary, the VAR could make the system stationary due to detrending, differencing
or cointergrating techniques. Following these authors, VAR should be investigated in levels
instead of differencing because differencing throws away important information. Thus,
the paper takes the natural logarithm of variables, except output gap IP (treated in
Hodrick‒Prescott filter) and lending interest rate IR. The results show that the natural
logarithm of variables ‒ denoted LOG(Y) ‒ makes the system stationary (Figure 1).
3.2 Lag length criteria
Determining lag length in VAR model is one of the most important requirements. Table I
shows the lag length criteria for VAR analysis.
–1.5
–1.0
–0.5
0.0
0.5
1.0
1.5
–1.5 –1.0 –0.5 0.0 0.5 1.0 1.5
Inverse Roots of AR Characteristic Polynomial
Source: Author’s estimation
Roots of Characteristic Polynomial
Endogenous variables: IP LCPI LM2 IR LREER
Exogenous variables: C LOIL
Lag specification: 1 1
Date: 10 June 2018 Time: 13:07
Root Modulus
0.992375 0.992375
0.908434 – 0.082988i 0.912217
0.908434 + 0.082988i 0.912217
0.900816 0.900816
0.576236 0.576236
No root lies outside the unit circle
VAR satisfies the stability condition
Figure 1.
Stationary
Lag LogL LR FPE AIC SC HQ
0 −278.1205 na 9.48e–05 4.925136 5.161219 5.020983
1 639.2593 1,724.988 2.25e–11 −10.32922 −9.502927* −9.993754
2 678.4208 70.28991 1.77e–11* −10.57130 −9.154796 −9.996214*
3 700.4518 37.65985 1.88e–11 −10.52054 −8.513836 −9.705845
4 715.3053 24.12110 2.26e–11 −10.34710 −7.750184 −9.292784
5 746.3144 47.70622 2.08e–11 −10.44982 −7.262694 −9.155885
6 773.8191 39.96410 2.05e–11 −10.49263 −6.715302 −8.959083
7 804.5918 42.08237* 1.93e–11 −10.59131 −6.223773 −8.818145
8 830.5531 33.28368 2.01e–11 −10.60774* −5.649997 −8.594960
Source: Author’s estimation
Table I.
Lag length criteria
148
JED
21,2
According to criteria AIC, SC and HQ, lag length should be 1, 2 or 8. As the number of
observations is limited over the period M1:2008‒M5:2018, the lag length is as small as
possible. The reason is that if the lag length is increased, the degree of freedom is decreased,
which might then affect the quality of the estimation. This is a reason why the paper
chooses one lag length for the model.
3.3 Chow test
The SBV changed the exchange rate policy at the end of 2015 and implemented it in the
beginning of 2016. Hence, there would have been a structural break to the official/nominal
exchange rate. In other words, it is necessary to apply a nonlinear model such as threshold
vector autoregression instead of a linear model such as vector autoregression.
Nevertheless, the paper uses the REER over full period 2008‒2018 instead of the
nominal exchange rate. This could help the model avoid structural break issues, as the
REER takes not only the nominal exchange rate of Vietnam but also various factors such
as inflation and exchange rate movements of the largest trading partner countries with
Vietnam. The REER reflects the “true” value of exchange rate of Vietnam over full period
2008‒2018, and it may not be affected by changes of the exchange rate policy in 2016. In
order to test whether there appears the structural break, the paper uses Chow test. Table II
provides results.
The empirical results implies that it cannot reject the null hypothesis that there is no
break at specified breakpoint (in January 2016 ‒ the beginning time to implement new
exchange rate policy). It means that there is no structural break for the model. Therefore, the
paper could use VAR model to investigate the exchange rate pass-through.
3.4 Impulse response test and pass-through coefficients
Figure 2 illustrates the impact of REER changes on inflation. Because the REER is behind
the consumer price index in the Cholesky triangle matrix, the shocks from REER to inflation
only occur in the next period. As expected, inflation decreases after the REER increases
(domestic currency appreciates). The interval confidence (red lines) mentions that result is
significant over 15 months. So if REER increases, then inflation decreases from 2nd month
onward and reaches maximum at 12th month.
To measure ERPT, many studies, for example McCarthy (2000), Leigh and Rossi (2002),
Ito and Sato (2006) and Lian (2006), used a standardized approach in which the standard
deviation of the exchange rate would be standardized to 1 percent increase in shock. At the
same time, when calculating ERPT, it is necessary to consider the response of exchange rate
due to its own shock in subsequent periods.
Applying the formula of Leigh and Rossi (2002) to measure the pass-through
coefficient (PT):
PTt; tþ i ¼ Pt; tþ i=Et; tþ i;
Chow Breakpoint Test: 2016M01
Null Hypothesis: No breaks at specified breakpoints
Varying repressors: All equation variables
Equation sample: 2008M01 2018M05
F-statistic 0.823642 Prob. F(6, 113) 0.5539
Log likelihood ratio 5.350489 Prob. χ2(6) 0.4997
Wald statistic 4.941852 Prob. χ2(6) 0.5513
Source: Author’s estimation
Table II.
Chow test
149
ERPT in
Vietnam
where Pt, t+i is price level change in period i in response to initial exchange rate shock and
Et, t+i is the accumulated exchange rate change in response to its own shocks.
So, the pass-through coefficients are provided in Table III.
As shown in Table III, the real effective ERPT is incomplete pass-through (less than
1 percent). Specifically, after the first three months, the pass-through coefficient is −0.05,
which means that 1 percent increase of the REER (i.e. appreciation) will cause the consumer
price to decrease by 0.05 percent. After the first six months, the pass-through coefficient is
−0.13, which means that 1 percent increase of the REER (i.e. appreciation) will cause
consumer prices to decrease by 0.13 percent. After 12 months, the pass-through coefficient is
−0.22, which means that 1 percent increase of the REER (i.e. appreciation) will cause
consumer prices to decrease by 0.22 percent. After 15 months, the pass-through coefficient is
−0.24, which means that 1 percent increase of the REER (i.e. appreciation) will cause
consumer prices to decrease by 0.24 percent. Thus, it can be said that the REER shocks have
a signinficant impact on consumer prices. Moreover, this is incomplete ERPT.
3.5 Variance decomposition
The paper uses Cholesky variance over a 15-month period because the impulse response of
consumer price level to REER is significant over the period of 15 months, as mentioned
above. According to Taylor (2000), in order to reinforce the result of ERPT, it is necessary to
analyze variance decomposition of inflation, apart from the impulse response. To be
more exact, if the real effective ERPT is high, this implies a strong transmission from
REER fluctuations to consumer price. However, if the REER slightly affects the variance
of the inflation, the REER is not an important factor to determine the fluctuations of
–0.012
–0.010
–0.008
–0.006
–0.004
–0.002
0.000
0.002
0.004
2 4 6 8 10 12 14 16 18 20 22 24
Response of LCPI to Cholesky One SD LREER Innovation
Source: Author’s estimation
Figure 2.
Impulse response
of CPI
Month CPI Month CPI
1 0.000000000 9 −0.182170388
2 −0.027774431 10 −0.196289103
3 −0.054789344 11 −0.208356451
4 −0.080579939 12 −0.218345799
5 −0.104765170 13 −0.226361291
6 −0.127124090 14 −0.232546249
7 −0.147550111 15 −0.237006336
8 −0.165902347
Source: Author’s estimation
Table III.
Pass-through
coefficients
150
JED
21,2
consumer price. Thus, it can be observed that analysis of the variance of inflation is very
essential (Table IV ).
The results in LCPI variance table show that LREER is a great factor to determine the
variance of LCPI among macroeconomic factors. It means that Vietnam has a relatively
significant transmission effect from the REER to inflation. Three months after the REER
shocks, LREER explains nearly 5 percent of LCPI variance or 5 percent of the inflation
influctuation is explained by REER. Six months after the REER shocks, LREER explains
nearly 22 percent of LCPI variance or 22 percent of the inflation influctuation is explained by
REER. In total, 12 months after the REER shocks, LREER explains nearly 43 percent of
LCPI variance or 43 percent of the inflation influctuation is explained by REER. Fifteen
months after the REER shocks, LREER explains nearly 47 percent of LCPI variance or
47 percent of the inflation influctuation is explained by REER. In the other words, it
confirms the significant role of the domestic currency appreciation/depreciation in inflation.
4. Discussion and policy implication
The paper applies VAR approach to investigate the ERPT over the period 2008‒2018.
From the paper’s results, it can be observed that the impact level of ERPT over the
post-WTO period is incomplete and less than that of ERPT over the ante-WTO period, as
seen in Vo (2009) and Nguyen et al. (2009). Although the impact level of ERPT tends
toward reducing, it is still significant based on impulse response of inflation to REER and
variance decomposition of inflation results. In other words, it is likely that the REER
significantly affects inflation. The paper’s results could be explained by some reasons,
which are given below.
First, in Vietnam, importers and their counterparts tend to adopt mark-up price, so the
increase/decrease in the exchange rate is almost transferred into the import price and then
consumer price. Goujon’s (2006) view is consistent with empirical studies by Ghei and
Pritchett (1999) and Feinberg (2000). These studies show that for small and developing
countries, exchange rate pass-through into import price and consumer price is higher than
the large and developed countries.
Second, in Vietnam, the inflation expectation makes the exchange rate and inflation
relationship to be more sensitive. When an appreciation/depreciation policy is implemented,
the people’s psychology about the appreciation/depreciation is stimulated, and the effect goes
Period SE IP LCPI LM2 IR LREER
1 8.720252 2.258229 97.74177 0.000000 0.000000 0.000000
2 10.34189 6.280352 91.15513 0.815911 0.002289 1.746313
3 11.00465 9.413639 82.44019 2.631441 0.023976 5.490750
4 11.34807 11.15179 73.02065 5.189604 0.077518 10.56043
5 11.56740 11.67044 63.78853 8.168619 0.159597 16.21282
6 11.73156 11.34866 55.28299 11.27675 0.257246 21.83436
7 11.86637 10.54909 47.77428 14.30056 0.356050 27.02002
8 11.98184 9.542362 41.33725 17.11213 0.444978 31.56328
9 12.08209 8.501954 35.92417 19.65265 0.517676 35.40355
10 12.16904 7.525351 31.42469 21.90951 0.571804 38.56865
11 12.24390 6.658938 27.70675 23.89639 0.607752 41.13018
12 12.30766 5.918144 24.64024 25.63940 0.627460 43.17476
13 12.36134 5.301285 22.10830 27.16858 0.633566 44.78826
14 12.40600 4.798218 20.01123 28.51338 0.628865 46.04831
15 12.44270 4.395363 18.26645 29.70051 0.616015 47.02166
Source: Author’s estimation
Table IV.
Variance
decomposition of LCPI
151
ERPT in
Vietnam
straight to the consumer price index instead of passing through the production channel.
Nguyen (2011) argued that in order to reduce negative effects from people’s psychology, the
Government should pay attention to control inflation even if inflation is at low level.
Exaggerated expectation of inflation reduces the effectiveness of macroeconomic policies.
Third, Vietnam is considered as a high dollarization country. Some commodities such as
real estate or fixed assets are usually quoted in US dollar. When the domestic currency
depreciates, these commodities tend to increase and indirectly increase inflation and vice
versa. Another point is that in Vietnam, money supply (M2) includes foreign currency
deposit. If foreign currency appreciates, money supply will increase and vice versa. In the
context of holding other macroeconomic factors constant, this will create impacts on price
level in Vietnam.
Fourth, Vietnam’s economy is highly dependent on imports for the domestic
consumption and the production. Thus, Vietnam is heavily affected by the inflation
import. If domestic currency value increases/decreases, it causes the price of imported goods
in the local currency to decrease/increase, hence contributing directly to influence the price
level of the country.
Finally, in Vietnam, domestic savings are not enough to meet the demand for investments,
so Vietnam’s economy is still growing due to foreign capital inflows. The appreciation/
depreciation of the domestic currency will decrease/increase capital cost, which implies a
decrease/increase in production costs, thus decreasing/increasing inflation.
To sum up, paper’s results related to impulse responses and variance decompositions
indicate that the inflation is significantly affected by REER shocks. Therefore, the exchange
rate policy could strongly influence macroeconomic factor, especially inflation. If the
exchange rate has to absorb negative shocks, it thus might influence inflation negatively.
During the post-WTO period, ERPT in Vietnam tends toward reducing its impact level. This
maybe due to the efficiency of SBV management on the exchange rate policy whereby SBV
permits the exchange rate to be more flexible. This then enhances the development of the
derivatives market, hedging the exchange rate risks for credit institutions and enterprises.
As a result, firms usually use derivative instruments and take fluctuations of the exchange
rate occurring in their products. Therefore, negative effects from the exchange rate changes
could be reduced. It means that the exchange rate mechanism implemented by SBV is
efficient, and the SBV needs to continue the exchange rate to be more flexible in line with the
development of economy.
5. Robustness of results
To test the robustness, the paper now changes variable for the baseline model. Instead of
using REER the paper uses nominal effective exchange rate, NEER. In this model, one lag is
used to estimate the impulse response of consumer price level to nominal effective exchange
rate in recursive zero contemporaneous restrictions. Following the result of impulse
response of inflation to nominal effective exchange rate, inflation decreases after the
nominal effective exchange rate increases (domestic currency appreciates). The interval
confidence mentions that result is significant over 15-month period. So if nominal effective
exchange rate increases, inflation decreases from the second month onward as nominal
effective exchange rate is behind consumer price index in Cholesky triangle.
Calculating the pass-through coefficient shows that the nominal effective ERPT is
incomplete and its absolute value is less than that of baseline model. Specifically, after the
first 3 months, the pass-through coefficient is −0.04, which means that 1 percent increase of
the NEER (i.e. appreciation), will cause the consumer price to decrease by 0.04 percent. After
the first six months, the pass-through coefficient is −0.09, which means that 1 percent
increase of the NEER (i.e. appreciation) will cause consumer prices to decrease by
0.09 percent. After 12 months, the pass-through coefficient is −0.15, it means that 1 percent
152
JED
21,2
increase of the NEER (i.e. appreciation) will cause consumer prices to decrease by 0.15 percent.
After 15 months, the pass-through coefficient is −0.17, it means that 1 percent increase of the
NEER (i.e. appreciation) will cause consumer prices to decrease by 0.17 percent.
The results of LCPI variance analysis show that LNEER is great factor to determine the
variance of LCPI among macroeconomic factors. However, its absolute value is less than
that of baseline model. Three months after the shocks, nearly 3 percent of the inflation
variance is determined by nominal effective exchange rate. Six months after the shocks,
nearly 13 percent of the inflation variance is determined by nominal effective exchange rate.
Twelve months after the shocks, nearly 34 percent the inflation variance is determined by
nominal effective exchange rate. Fifteen months after the shocks, nearly 40 percent the
inflation variance is determined by nominal effective exchange rate.
6. Conclusion
The paper measures the ERPT on the basis of VAR. The empirical results point out that
ERPT is incomplete (less than 1 percent); specifically, the pass-through coefficient is −0.05
after 3 months; −0.13 after 6 months; −0.22 after 12 months; and −0.24 after 15 months.
It means that 1 percent increase in the REER (i.e. appreciation) will decrease CPI by
0.05 percent over the next 3 months; by 0.13 percent after 6 months; by 0.22 percent after
12 months; and by 0.24 percent after 15 months. In addition, the variance analysis suggests
that the REER may explain about 5 percent of the change in inflation after 3 months;
22 percent after 6 months; 43 percent after 12 months; and 47 percent after 15 months. This
evidence argues that the REER significantly affects inflation in Vietnam.
Future work: because of the data limitation, this paper has not yet investigated and
compared ERPT in two different periods, which reflects two different exchange rate
regimes: from 2008 to 2015 and from 2016 onward:
(1) From 2008 to 2015, SBV applied the exchange rate mechanism through the average
interbank exchange rate tool and the exchange rate band. Specifically, the average
exchange rate in the interbank market in the previous day was the index basis for
determining the next day’s exchange rate. SBV regulated the trading band in each
period, and it directly intervened in the interbank foreign exchange market to
monitor the daily exchange rate.
(2) From 2016 onward, SBV has applied the exchange rate mechanism through the
central exchange rate tool and the exchange rate band. The central exchange rate is
determined by domestic and foreign factors, such as the average exchange rate in
the interbank foreign currency market; exchange rates in the international market of
some largest trading partner countries’s currencies; and balance on macroeconomic
and monetary policy.
So in the future, research studies could investigate and compare ERPT in two different
exchange rate regimes. By doing this work, they could find the exchange rate regime,
2008‒2015 exchange rate regime or 2016 onward exchange rate regime, that affects inflation
more significantly.
References
Belaish, A. (2003), “Exchange rate pass-through in Brazil”, IMF Working Paper No. 03/141,
International Monetary Fund, Paris, July.
Bernanke, B.S. and Mihov, I. (1998), “Measuring monetary policy”, The Quarterly Journal of Economics,
Vol. 113 No. 3, pp. 869-902.
Campa, J.M. and Goldberg, L.S. (2005), “Exchange rate pass through into import prices”, Review of
Economics and Statistics, Vol. 87 No. 4, pp. 679-690.
153
ERPT in
Vietnam
Campa, J.M., Goldberg, L.S. and González-Mínguez, J.M. (2005), “Exchange rate pass-through
to import prices in the Euro Area”, NBER Working Paper No. 11632, Federal Reserve Bank of
New York, NY, September.
Dornbursch, R. (1987), “Exchange rate and prices”, The American Economic Review, Vol. 77 No. 1,
pp. 93-106.
Faruqee, H. (2006), “Exchange rate pass through in the Euro Area”, International Monetary Fund
Working Paper No. 1, Vol. 53, Washington, DC, April.
Feinberg, R.M. (1986), “The interaction of foreign exchange and market power effects on German
domestic prices”, Journal of Industrial Economics, Vol. 35 No. 1, pp. 61-70.
Feinberg, R.M. (2000), “The role of international discipline in three developing economies: exchange
rate effects on domestic prices in Colombia, Korea and Morocco”, Review of International
Economics, Vol. 8 No. 1, pp. 126-133.
Friedman, M. (1963), Inflation: Causes and Consequences, Asia Publishing Rouse, Bombay.
Fujiwara, I. (2003), “Output composition of the monetary policy transmission mechanism in Japan”,
Bank of Japan Working Paper Series No. 03-E-9, Tokyo.
Ghei, N. and Pritchett, L. (1999), The Three Pessimissions: Real Exchange Rate and Trade Flows in
Developing Countries, World Bank Research Publication, Oxford University Press, New York, NY.
Goldberg, P.K. and Knetter, M. (1997), “Goods prices and exchange rates: what have we learned?”,
Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. 35 No. 3, pp. 1243-1272.
Goujon, M. (2006), “Fighting inflation in a dollarized economy: the case of Vietnam”, Journal of
Comparative Economics, Vol. 34 No. 3, pp. 564-581.
Hahn, E. (2003), “Pass through of external shocks to Euro area inflation”, Working Paper No. 243,
European Central Bank, Frankfurt, July.
Ito, T. and Sato, K. (2006), “Exchange rate changes and inflation in post-crisis Asian economies: VAR
analysis of the exchange rate pass through”, Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, Vol. 40 No. 7,
pp. 1407-1438.
Krugman, P. (1986), Pricing-to-market When the Exchange Rates Changes, MIT Press, Cambridge.
Leigh, D. and Rossi, M. (2002), “Exchange rate pass through in Turkey”, IMF Working Paper
No. WP/02/204, National Bureau of Economic Research, February 2004.
Lian, A. (2006), “Exchange rate pass through: evidence base on Vector Autoregression with sign
restrictions”, Munich Personal RePEc Archive Paper No. 527, UTC, October.
McCarthy, J. (2000), “Pass through of exchange rates import prices to domestic inflation in some
industrialized economies”, Eastern Economic Journal, Vol. 33 No. 4, pp. 511-537.
Nguyen, M.A.D., Tran, A.M. and Vo, T.T. (2009), “Exchange rate pass-through into inflation in Vietnam:
an assessment using vector autoregression approach”, Vietnam Economic Management Review,
Vol. 1 No. 3, pp. 1-16.
Nguyen, T.H. (2011), “Luá cho
˙
n chính sách tỳ giá”, Vietnam Institute for Economic and Policy
Research, Vietnam National University.
Olivei, G. (2002), “Exchange rate and the prices of manufacturing products imported into United
States”, New England Economic Review, First Quarter, Vol. 1 No. 3, pp. 3-18.
Otani, A., Shiratsuka, S. and Shirota, T. (2005), “Revisiting the decline in the exchange rate
pass through: further evidence from Japan’s import prices”, IMES Discussion Paper Series
No. 2005-E-6, Bank of Japan, Tokyo, July.
Sims, C.A., Stock, J.H. and Watson, M.W. (1990), “Inference in linear time series models with some unit
roots”, Econometrica, Vol. 58 No. 1, p. 113.
Taylor, J.B. (2000), “Low inflation, pass through, and the pricing power of firms”, European Economic
Review, Vol. 44 No. 7, pp. 1389-1408.
Vo, M.V. (2009), “Exchange rate pass through and its implications for inflation in Vietnam”, working
paper, Vietnam Development Forum, Ha Noi, February.
154
JED
21,2
Further reading
Gagnon, J.E. and Ihrig, J. (2004), “Monetary policy and exchange rate pass through”, International
Journal of Finance and Economics, Vol. 41 No. 2, pp. 291-310.
Junior, R.P.N. (2007), “Inflation targeting and exchange rate pass-through”, Economia Aplicada, Vol. 11
No. 2, pp. 189-208.
Junttila, J. and Korhonen, M. (2012), “The role of inflation regime in the exchange rate pass-through to
import prices”, International Review of Economics & Finance, Vol. 20 No. 2, pp. 88-96.
Mann, C.L. (1986), “Prices, profit margins, and exchange rate”, Federal Reserve Bulletin, Vol. 72 No. 6,
pp. 360-379.
Nguyen, P.T. and Nguyen, T.D. (2009), “Exchange rate policy in Vietnam, 1985-2008”, Asian Economic
Bulletin, Vol. 26 No. 2, pp. 113-163.
Nicoleta, C. (2007), “Estimating the exchange rate pass through into inflation in a vector autoregressive
framework”, The Journal of the Faculty of Economics – Economic Science Series, Vol. 2 No. 5,
pp. 231-233.
Vo, T.T. (1997), “Exchange rate in Viet Nam”, working paper, Central Institute for Economic
Management, Ha Noi.
Corresponding author
Van Anh Pham can be contacted at: phamvaananh@gmail.com
For instructions on how to order reprints of this article, please visit our website:
www.emeraldgrouppublishing.com/licensing/reprints.htm
Or contact us for further details: permissions@emeraldinsight.com
155
ERPT in
Vietnam
Các file đính kèm theo tài liệu này:
- exchange_rate_pass_through_into_inflation_in_viet_nam_eviden.pdf