1. introduction
2. the stylized facts
2.1. risk and return of international stock markets
2.2. implied volatility and return
2.3. the relationship between the S&P 500 and the corporate spreads
2.4. measuring the volatility: GARCH modelling
3. financial economics interpretation
3.1. financial economics fundamentals
3.2. intertemporal consumption based models
3.3. conclusion from classical finance evidence
3.4. option pricing Theory
3.5. corporate finance approach
3.6. conclusion
4. non – classical finance
4.1. behavioural finance
4.2. conclusion from non – classical finance
5. coclusion
Appendices
References
83 trang |
Chia sẻ: maiphuongtl | Lượt xem: 2293 | Lượt tải: 0
Bạn đang xem trước 20 trang tài liệu Stock market volatility: A puzzle? An investigation into the causes and consequences of asymmetric volatility, để xem tài liệu hoàn chỉnh bạn click vào nút DOWNLOAD ở trên
he noted that noise makes financial markets
possible, but also makes them imperfect. In addition to this, he pointed out that people who trade on
noise are willing to trade even though, from an objective point of view, they would be better off not
trading. Perhaps they think the noise they are trading on is information. In doing this continuous
trading without relevant firm news, Black supposed that this would cause the large fluctuation of the
stock market. Hence noise trading combined with “financial leverage” is the main volatility driver of
the stock market. The two effects combined could also perhaps affect the asymmetric volatility found
in empirical research. We already know the low level of empirical support for the leverage effect and,
from the literature, we also know that the noise trader models are not fully convincing.
De Long, et al. (1990) follow a somewhat different direction of reasoning about noise traders. In fact,
they postulated that many investors do not follow the economic advice of market efficiency.
Therefore, they do not buy the market portfolio, instead taking a position on single stocks following
some rather “irrational” chart based trading strategy. In reality, we know that if markets are efficient,
then technical analysis is useless in making a decision to buy or sell stocks. Their main point is that
arbitrageurs are risk averse and have reasonably short investment horizons. As a consequence, the
positions they are willing to hold against noise traders are limited.
Stock Markets Volatility: A Puzzle? Boris F. Papa
- 61 -
Noise traders falsely believe that they have special information about future prices of the risky assets.
Thus, they select their portfolios on the basis of such incorrect beliefs. But there is also a second
source of risk, the risk that noise trader activity is strong enough to stop prices from the mean
reverting over a long time. If these noise traders are able to move prices away from the fundamental
value, than rational arbitrageurs, who select their trade based on fundamental information, could suffer
losses because of this noise trading. As a consequence, they will not bet against the noise trader
decision, although they have better information and they know the right price. So in this battle, the
noise traders move asset price sharply away from the “fair value”. We ask ourselves, how is it possible
that only the arbitrageur would suffer from losses and not also the noise trader, who, in the end, will
just obtain gains for luck, yet on the average and in the long run, should not earn “free money”?
Connected to this is the still-open question of whether the arbitrage is limited. The answer is not clear-
cut. But evidence that two different shares of the same company (such as Shell and Royal Dutch)
could be traded at different prices for a long time, is some evidence for persistence in mispricing, and
the consequences for trying to exploit this mispricing could be fatal (see the experience of LTCM).
De Long, et al. (1990) reasoning is different. They conclude that noise traders are rewarded for
bearing the risk they themselves create. As a result, noise traders will earn higher returns from
holdings these assets. But this conclusion somewhat contradicts standard finance theory because it
postulates that only undiversifiable risk will have a premium, since this cannot be taken away. Hence,
the diversifiable risk should not bear any risk premium. It seems to us that this noise trading is rather a
diversifiable risk.
De Long, et al. developed an analytical model, which we cannot examine here for reasons of time and
space. They applied these models to some market anomalies, such as the closed-end-puzzle, the equity
premium puzzle and others. With this model, it should be possible also to explain the excess volatility
because noise traders push price far from the fundamental one and, in doing so, the risk, i.e., volatility,
may rise. So in the end, the argument is just slightly more formal than that of Black (1986), but not
sufficiently so to explain the observed market volatility. We are also sceptical of the argument because
it seems nearly impossible that this category of traders, which seems to be very small in practice,
could have so a large an impact on asset price for as big a stock market as the USA. For this reason,
we do not follow this theory any further in explaining stock market volatility and, instead, go to one
(perhaps the only one at the moment) asset pricing theory, which makes use in some form of the
behavioural finance and prospect theory, in particular, to explain volatility.
4.1.3. Prospect Theory and Asset Pricing
We will describe in this section the model derived by Barberis, et al. (2001) in a very influential paper.
This is (at least to our knowledge) the first attempt to implement the new findings of prospect theory
and behavioural finance in an asset pricing model. Moreover, it is perhaps the first attempt to combine
the “classical framework” of maximisation of final consumption over an infinite time horizon, with the
prospect theory findings of loss aversion. Therefore, the model presented here is not only interesting
for theoretical reasons, but could have a very large impact on asset pricing theory.
Barberis , et al. (2001), began by describing three “puzzles” that the classical standard finance theory
of consumption-based model cannot explain. The three identified puzzles are: 1) the equity premium
puzzle; 2) the volatility puzzle; and 3) the predictability puzzle. We have already seen and described
the first one. They defined the volatility puzzle as the stock market levels that appear to move around
too much (standard excess volatility). The argument here is as follows. Price to earnings has been
historically very high (at least for the USA market), which can be interpreted as future high cash flows
of firms. But historical data show that higher earnings do not follow historically higher P/E ratios. The
puzzle exists in the question of why the price was so high in the beginning, i.e., the volatility puzzle.
The predictability puzzle goes in the opposite direction: There is a lot of empirical evidence that high
P/E ratios are followed by low returns and vice versa.
Stock Markets Volatility: A Puzzle? Boris F. Papa
- 62 -
4.1.3.1. Investor preferences and the main
assumptions
The starting point of the model is the traditional classical model of Lucas (1978), that we have
described extensively in Chapter 3. We use the same notations as the original paper for at least two
reasons. First of all, so it will be consistent with the original one, and, secondly, to make a clear
distinction between this model and the many we have seen in chapter three, although the methodology
will remain more or less the same. The model works with the classical standard power utility function
for the consumption part and a modified version of the cumulative prospect theory of Tversky and
Kahneman. In particular, agents are assumed to maximise following expected value:
( )
+−Ε ∑
∞
=
+
+
−
0 2
1
1
1
1
1t
ttt
t
t
tt zSXvbC
,,ργρ
γ
(4.7)
The first term (1) is the standard classical maximisation problem that we have seen in chapter 3 (see
above for interpretation of the variables). The C is just the consumption, the factor ρ is the standard
time discount factor for time t or for time t+1, and γ is the common curvature of utility over
consumption. The second term (2) represents utility from fluctuations in the value of financial wealth
and incorporate an extended prospect theory “value function”. This is a function of the gains or losses
( 1+tX ) over the next period, the security price ( tS ), and a state variable ( tz ) which measures the
investor’s gains or losses prior to time t as a fraction of tS ; in other words, the past performance of
risky asset. Finally, tb is an exogenous scaling factor. From (4.7), one can see why we called this new
approach to asset pricing “the modern finance synthesis” because it combines the classical
consumption theory and the behavioural part in which investors derive utility also in the future stock
market performance. Nothing is said in this model about rationality of investors, but the authors
pointed out that this model is not incompatible with rationality and, in this sense, is just an extension
of the classical model that we have already seen with the Epstein and Zin utility function. To follow
this, we should briefly overview the variables, which enter into the model.
Gains and losses ( 1+tX ) are measured with respect to the returns on the risky asset, but also scaled up
by the risk free rate to find the reference level. This means that investors are interested in the excess
return over some period (1 year for practicality) and derive from this utility:
tftttt RSRSX ,−= ++ 11
where tS is the stock price, 1+tR is the next period return and tfR , is the risk free return over the next
period know in advance at time t.
To capture the influence of prior outcomes, they introduce the concept of historical benchmark level
tZ for the value of the risky asset. This is just to capture the fact that a loss following another loss has
a much higher impact on an investor’s risky asset holdings than a loss after a long period of gains. It
introduces a dependence structure on the past performance quite similar to the reasoning that we have
seen in habit formation of Campbell and Cochrane (1999). In contradiction to this model, this time the
reference is not the consumption, but the portfolio returns. For modelling purposes, they find it
convenient to write the scaled past performance as
t
t
t S
Zz = . From this, it follows that we can
distinguish three distinct cases: 1=tz , where the investor has neither prior gains nor prior losses on
Stock Markets Volatility: A Puzzle? Boris F. Papa
- 63 -
his investments; 1tz , the case of prior losses. For each of these
cases, they derived a functional form of the utility function. Starting with 1=tz , or just to catch the
loss aversion of investors, we have
( )
0
0
1
1
1
1 <
≥
=
+
+
+
+
+
1t
1t
t
t
tt X
X
for
X
X
SXv λ,, (4.8)
where λ>1 is. The intuition here is that an investor with a cushion of past gains may not care
about small losses, but large losses may matter. For the case of 1≤tz , considering a scaling risk free
rate, we have the following functional form:
( ) ( ) ( ) tft1t tft1ttfttttftftt tftttttt RzR
RzR
for RzRSRRzS
RSRS
zSXv
,
,
,,,
,,, <
≥
−+−
−=
+
+
+
+
+
1
1
1 λ (4.9)
Finally, we have to consider the case of 1>tz , when investors have experienced some losses, we
have:
( ) ( ) 0
0
1
1
1 <
≥
=
+
+
+
+
+
1t
1t
tt
t
ttt X
X
for
Xz
X
zSXv λ,, (4.10)
where ( )tzλ >λ is, and this considers some penalty function dependent on past losses:
( ) ( )1−+= tt zkz λλ (4.11)
where k>0 is. The larger the past loss, the more painful subsequent loss will be.
These three characterizations fully describe the utility function of the investor derived from the stock
market and past returns. If we look more closely, we can see that the functional form of (4.8) is
somewhat similar to the original prospect theory proposed by T&K. However, the other two are
clearly new extensions,which captures the fact that past loss may influence more or less the investor
reaction to a new downward market, dependent upon whether the past has been very successful or less
successful. These three characterizations determine the curvature of the value function in the negative
part: it is more pronounced in the third case and less in the first one, although the curvature changes
suddenly if the investor perceives the loss could be persistent and so becomes more loss averse.
Finally, we should consider the scaling factor tb , which is important to maintain the stationarity of
risk premium because an increasing second term would imply a domination over the first as wealth
increases. To satisfy this condition, the authors introduce the scaling factor as:
γ−= tt Cbb 0 (4.12)
where tC is the aggregate per-capita consumption at time t, and hence exogenously given. 0b is a
positive constant factor. If it is zero, then (4.7) it reduces just to the traditional standard classical
model.
Thus, the proposed model of Barberis, et al., incorporates some features of prospect theory, but not all.
They neglect the transformation of probability, for instance, and the value function is a little bit
different, as we have seen above. But the most important fact that investors are loss averse, if they
have already had a loss, is well implemented. On this point, there is some contradiction in the
literature because some authors consider “risk seeking” behaviour of investors after a loss. This is
Stock Markets Volatility: A Puzzle? Boris F. Papa
- 64 -
experimentally unfounded, and also, in practice, people consider loss averse investors as the “normal
case”. Of course, if an investor has a lot of losses and perceives for any reason some probability of
rebound of the market, than he becomes more risk seeking. This feature can very well be observed in
other games like casino, slot machine and poker. People that lose a lot try everything to a least break
even. The literature on probability is rich here: The ruin theory is commonly known as “don’t play the
martingale!” In this case, if you play the supermartingale, you will, on the average lose money almost
surely.
4.1.3.2. The model
In the original (Barberis, et al. 2001) paper, the authors derived the asset pricing formula in two
different economies. The first is like the Lucas model, where the dividends and consumption follow
the same process. The second is where the dividends and consumption follow two different processes.
We will have a look only at the second because the first economy is too similar to the models we have
seen in chapter 3. In addition to this, the second is so general that it includes the first as a special case.
They assume that the risk free rate is constant and the equilibrium is a one-factor Markov, driven by
the state variable tz , which determines the distribution of future stock returns. In addition to this, the
price-dividend ratio of stock is a function of the state variable tz :
( )t
t
t
t zfD
Pf =≡ (4.13)
Given the one-factor assumption, the distribution of stock returns 1+tR is determined by tz and the
function f() using:
( )
( ) t
t
t
t
t
tt
t D
D
zf
zf
P
DPR 1111
1 +++
+
+=+= (4.14)
Than the processes followed by consumption and dividends are:
1
1
+
+ +=
tCC
t
t g
C
Clog ησ (4.15)
1
1
+
+ +=
tDD
t
t g
D
D
log εσ (4.16)
where
1
1
0
0
w
w
Ndii
t
t ;...~ε
η
This last assumption, which makes
t
t
D
Clog a random walk, allows us to construct a one-factor
Markov equilibrium in which risk free rate is constant. This means that the stock returns is
( )
( ) 111
1 ++++
+= tDDg
t
t
t ezf
zfR εσ (4.16)
Stock Markets Volatility: A Puzzle? Boris F. Papa
- 65 -
The first order conditions for an optimum are than a pair of Euler equation:
Ε=
−
+
γ
ρ
t
t
tf C
CR 11 , and (4.17)
( )[ ]ttt
t
t
tt zRvbC
CR ,ˆ 10
1
11 +
−
+
+ Ε+
Ε= ρρ
γ
(4.18)
where for 1<tz ,
( ) ( ) ( ) tft1t tft1ttftttftft tfttt RzR
RzR
for RzRRRz
RR
zRv
,
,
,,,
,,ˆ <
≥
−+−
−=
+
+
+
+
+
1
1
1 λ (4.19)
and for 1>tz
( ) ( )( ) tf1t tf1ttftt tfttt RR
RR
for RRz
RR
zRv
,
,
,
,,ˆ <
≥
−
−=
+
+
+
+
+
1
1
1 λ (4.20)
This optimal equation are similar to those seen in chapter 3, also the interpretation is similar. The only
changes here is that consuming less today to invest in the risky asset exposes the investor to greater
losses, which depends on the state variable tz .
Given this they has been able to proof the following proposition:
Proposition 4. 1:
The risk free is constant at 21
22
CCg
f eR
σγγρ −−= (4.21)
And the stock’s price-dividend ratio f() is given by:
( ) ( )
( ) ( )
( )
( )
+Ε+
+Ε= ++ ++−+−+− tg
t
t
t
w
t
t
t
wgg
ze
zf
zf
vbe
zf
zf
e tDDtCDCCD ,ˆ 11
222
1
0
112
1 11
1 εσεσγσ
σγγ ρρ (4.22)
where vˆ is given by (4.19) and (4.20).
Proof: See Barberis, et al. (2001, Appendix)
4.1.3.3. Model results and interpretation
If you take the logarithm of formula 4.21, the risk free rate is similar to that derived in (3.50) above,
apart from some other parameters. The second equation in (4.22) is really complex and not so easy to
understand. Moreover, there exists no closed form analytical solution, and it is necessary to run
numerical methods to solve it. The authors pointed out that in numerical tests, this model has been
able to show low consumption volatility and high stock returns volatility, while maintaining low stable
risk free rate and low correlation of stock returns to the consumption. These results, of course, comply
well with the findings in many empirical studies. Thus, one may conclude that this model is an
improvement of the habit-formation one of Campbell and Cochrane, and can well explain the asset
pricing and the numerous puzzles found with classical models. In addition to this, it is easy to explain
the high equity premium and also the asymmetrical volatility. Investors are loss averse; therefore they
ask high risk premiums to prevent them from losses in holding risky assets. Also, and for perhaps the
same reason, they increase the volatility of stock prices when they drop. This is because they become
Stock Markets Volatility: A Puzzle? Boris F. Papa
- 66 -
very loss averse and prefer to sell risky assets, reinvest the proceeds in the risk free rate, thus pushing
down the latter and the risky asset price, pushing up the volatility of stock returns.
Although the authors concluded that a model that relies on loss aversion alone cannot provide a
complete description of aggregate stock market behaviour, they added that the fundamental weakness
of such a model comes in explaining the volatility which is too low to be compatible with the real data.
We can conclude by saying that this is a great step forward in explaining asset pricing and loss
aversion, but perhaps it needs some degree of refinement. We can also comment that this is “reversal
engineering” modelling, as in Campbell and Cochrane (1999). These models are constructed so that
they can provide a good explanation of the data, but many unanswered questions remain about
prediction and reliability of such models. In our opinion, there are still too many assumptions. The
models are very sensitive to the estimate of the parameters, which can be seen as the major drawback.
Whether or not these models are in compliance with other models in macroeconomics that explain an
agent’s decision-making and behaviour is still an open question. Also, the attempt to combine the
classical with the new prospect theory is courageous on the one hand, but is misleading on the other
because of the potential difficulty in really supporting the validity of the two theories combined.
Nevertheless, future research will probably involve a further attempt to combine the better of the two
theories. More psychology must be included in these models, but how do we model human behaviour
and human psychology with a simple mathematical model? If we cannot answer this question, then
models may be of little or no use.
4.2. Conclusion from Non-Classical Finance
“I don’t believe in mathematics”
Albert Einstein
Behavioural finance is a new branch of financial economics that attempts to analyse and explain many
financial market anomalies using non-standard financial methods. The market efficiency hypothesis,
the rationality of investors, and above all, the expected utility function failed completely to explain
market returns and agent decision-making. From this starting point, behavioural finance raises many
human preference and belief hypotheses and, using psychological phenomena, it also tries to explain
the numerous puzzles. The most important of the mainstream behavioural theories is the Prospect
Theory founded by Kahneman and Tversky in 1979. They further developed it in 1992, leading to the
cumulative prospect theory. The central idea of this new theory is the fact that people overestimate
lower probabilities and underestimate higher ones. In addition to this, people are risk averse for gains
and risk seeking for losses. This leads to an S-shaped value function. The main idea is that investors
are loss averse, trying to do everything to avoid losses.
Barberis, et al. (2001) was one of the first to use the prospect theory value function in connection with
some standard consumption power function. The idea has been to integrate into one model the utility
derived from consumption with that derived from investment in the risky asset. These authors
introduced a new feature of loss aversion. Investors care about past performance in the stock market.
They begin to change their attitude toward risky assets if they have registered successive losses.
Within this complex model, where some parameters are questionable, one is in the position to explain
many asset pricing puzzles. In addition to this, through the loss aversion, investors will cut losses, thus
suddenly inducing the asymmetric volatility phenomena. The authors provided many numerical
simulations to show the validity of such modelling. In addition to the well-known problem of
consumer-based models, this new feature of past performance dependency of the value function makes
the testing and tractability of such a model very difficult. Nevertheless, we are convinced that the
breakthrough of this new model could lead to some interesting further research and results.
Stock Markets Volatility: A Puzzle? Boris F. Papa
- 67 -
Behavioural Finance has had much criticism from “classical” finance researchers, foremost Eugene
Fama, who believes in the efficient markets hypothesis. Another well-known researcher is Mark
Rubistein (2000, p.17), who maintained that “many so called anomalies are empirical illusions created
by data mining, survivorship bias, selection bias, short-shot bias, trading costs, and the high variance
of sample means”. We will not comment here on this statement. However, we should at least admit
that empirical research is not the last word because, depending upon how one selects data, selects the
data time period, and looks at or analyses the data, one can find some is used, interesting relationships
or contradictions of some other research.
The best example is the momentum strategy of Jegadeesh and Titman (1993). In fact, their empirical
findings show how past winners consistently outperformed past losers, if one uses a window of six to
twelve months. Contrary to this, De Bondt and Thaler (1985) find empirically that up to a five-year
portfolio of past losers beat a portfolio of past winners. They explain this with representativeness
heuristic. Can this test contradict the former one? Or is it just another test? Many of these questions
related to empirical finance are still unanswered. Nonetheless, we can claim that behavioural finance
has revolutionized financial economic theory and changed it for the better. Future research will show
us if it will remain a separate branch of financial economics or if it will become an integrated part of
standard theory. We are convinced that future research will be more important. One cannot neglect
human behaviour and anomalies in analysing risky asset pricing and volatility. In the end, stock prices,
returns and volatility are always and everywhere the results of human action and not always in
compliance with models or quantitative financial analysis.
Stock Markets Volatility: A Puzzle? Boris F. Papa
- 68 -
5. Conclusion
“Man is not a circle with a single centre; he is an ellipse with two foci.
Facts are one, ideas are the other”
Victor Hugo, Les Miserables
In this paper we have analysed international stock market volatilities and found the commonly- known
stylised facts. In addition to this, one of the characteristics of stock market volatility is the asymmetric
behaviour: When the stock market declines, volatility increases more than when the stock market rises.
This asymmetrical behaviour of stock market volatility represents a puzzle that standard financial
economics cannot explain. To some extent, new consumption-based models that include habit
formation can explain this puzzle. However, if one looks in detail, this is the result of some financial
engineering, which can be difficult to explain with economics. The habit formation model of Campbell
and Cochrane (1999) is one of these successful examples. They provide at least some support for the
empirical validity of such a model. Within this model is also a possible explanation of some stylised
facts about consumption. In fact, the consumption smoothing and low correlation with the stock
market can be explained well.
Asymmetrical volatility is the cause of skewness and fat tail in the distribution of returns. This leads to
many problems for the standard model in finance. For the mean-variance approach, it means that the
variance is very high in a downmarket when the returns are very low, leading to inefficient portfolios.
This can be explained by a trader view of “rebound.” For the CAPM, asymmetrical volatility means
higher correlation, which should compensate the higher variance, but also lower expected returns; or,
if we do not assume it as a constant, higher equity premium. This is not the case in empirical findings.
The consequences for the Hansen-Jagannathan lower bound is that the assumed complete market and
perfect correlation no longer work. As a result, the stochastic discounted factor is very volatile and the
bound is not so well defined. The option pricing theory is also challenged by the stochastic volatility.
The market is incomplete and there is difficulty in finding a risk neutral probability, which makes a
discounted security a martingale. In addition to the volatility smile, one may find that there is higher
implied volatility when the market corrects than when the market rises. The theory of long call when
this happens has been exposed, although it is not very convincing. Analysing the VIX index, we find
that negative return is related to higher change in implied volatility, as is the positive return. This leads
to another side of the asymmetrical volatility. Corporate finance theory explains that a decline in the
stock market leads to decreasing equity compared to debt and to an increase of the leverage effect,
which should cause higher volatility. In many empirical studies, this leverage effect has not been very
successful in explaining volatility. For example, with Enron the leverage effect can explain only a
small part of the variance.
The empirical evidence of anomalies and puzzles gives support for a new financial theory based on the
psychological phenomenon of human beings. Prospect theory is the main framework in the
behavioural finance. The primary basis of this theory is that investors are loss averse, which leads to
asymmetrical behavioural to returns, thus causing the asymmetrical volatility. Application of this to
asset pricing, Barberis, et al. (2001), has shown that it can explain many puzzles, including the equity
premium puzzle and the asymmetric volatility. The introduction of the idea of noise trading risk raises
the issue of higher volatility. These models attempt to explain how uninformed traders can limit the
arbitrage and increase the volatility. Nevertheless, it remains difficult to test. Pure psychological
explanation of human behaviour can also explain the asymmetric volatility. Cognitive dissonance
appears when people discover that they can be wrong. To minimise this dissonance, they sell risky
assets when the stock market decreases, pushing returns down and volatility up.
Many classical financial economists are sceptical about the many anomalies found by behavioural
finance. Fama interprets the fact that both overreaction and underreaction are observed in financial
markets as evidence that the anomalies from the standpoint of efficient markets theory are just “chance
Stock Markets Volatility: A Puzzle? Boris F. Papa
- 69 -
results.” Therefore, the theory of market efficiency survives the challenge of its critics. In fact, Fama
states that the literature on testing market efficiency has no clearly stated alternative since the
alternative hypothesis is vague market efficiency. Mark Rubinstein (2001) describes the “Prime
Directive” of financial economists to be to: “explain asset prices by rational models, only if all
attempts fail resort to irrational investor behaviour.” Steve Ross (2001) offers the following statement:
“At present, behavioural finance seems more defined by what it doesn’t like about neo-classical
finance than what it has to offer as an alternative”. He than added, that ”behaviouralists are surely
right about one thing: most of the time most of the people do, indeed, misbehave”.
Richard Thaler (1999) anticipates the future integration of behavioural finance within the “standard”
paradigm: “In the future financial economists will routinely incorporate as much behaviour into their
models as they observe in the real world”. If this is really so, in order to solve the puzzle, satisfactory
models of „stock market volatility“ may have to wait until behavioural finance develops human
behaviour models related to the stock market that can properly coordinate with standard finance
economics. Only time will tell.
Stock Markets Volatility: A Puzzle? Boris F. Papa
- 70 -
Appendices
Appendix I
Figure A. I: Density estimate for MSCI Stock Price Index
Appendix II
Stock Markets Volatility: A Puzzle? Boris F. Papa
- 71 -
Figure A. II: Density estimate for Swiss Stock Price Index compared to the Gaussian density
Appendix III
Figure A. III: Annualised excess returns and volatility of international stock markets (MSCI Price index).
Stock Markets Volatility: A Puzzle? Boris F. Papa
- 72 -
Appendix IV
Figure A. IV: Some plot of annualised GARCH volatility for the international stock markets
Stock Markets Volatility: A Puzzle? Boris F. Papa
- 73 -
Appendix V
One may consider a maximal correlation between the two SDFs and get
( )( ) ( )( ) ( ) ( )( ) ( ) ( ) ( )[ ]
( )( ) ( )( ) ( ) ( )( )
( )( ) ( ) ( )( )
( ) ( )( ) ( )( ) ( )( ) ( )( )
( ) ( )( ) ( )( ) ( )( ) ( )( )22
0
VarVarVar,
or ,VarVarVar,
,CVar 0
,CVarVar
,-VarVarVar
LLLLLLLLLLCorr
LLLLLLLLLLCorr
LLLLovLL
LLLLovLLLL
LLLLLLCovLLLLLLLL
ttttt
ttttt
ttt
tttt
ttttttt
∗∗∗
∗∗∗
∗∗
∗∗
∗
≈
∗∗
=
=
−=
−+=
−++=
So, the desired result finally follows
( )( ) ( )( )( ) ( )( ) .,
Var
Var 2LLLLCorr
LLLL
tt
t
t ∗
∗
= (AV.1)
Stock Markets Volatility: A Puzzle? Boris F. Papa
- 74 -
References
Abel Andrew B. (1988): “Stock Prices under Time Varying Dividend Risk: An Exact
Solution in an Infinite-Horizon General Equilibrium Model” Journal of Monetary
Economics, 22, 375-393.
Abel Andrew B. (1990): “Asset Prices under Habit Formation and Catching Up with The
Joneses” American Economic Review , 80, Papers and Proceedings, 38-42.
Ait-Sahalia, Yacine, and Andrew W. Lo (2000): “Nonparametric risk management and
Implied Risk Aversion”, Journal of Econometrics, 94, 9-51.
Andersen, Torben G., Tim Bollerslev, Francis X. Diebold and Paul Labys, (1999):“Realized
Volatility and Correlation“, Working Paper of the National Science Foundation.
Arnott, Robert D., and Peter L. Bernstein (2002): “What Risk Premium is “Normal”?”,
Financial Analysts Journal, vol., March-April, 64-85.
Arrow, Kenneth J. and Gerard Debreu, (1954):”Existence of an Equilibrium for a
Competitive Economy”, Econometrica, 22, 265-290.
Banz, R., (1981): “The Relationship between Return and Market Value of Common Stocks”,
Journal of Financial Economics 9.
Barberis, Nicholas, Ming Huang, and Tano Santos (2001): “ Prospect Theory and Asset
Prices”, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 116, 1-53.
Barberis, Nicholas, Richard H. Thaler (2003): “A Survey of Behavioural Finance”,
Handbook of the Economics of Finance, Edited by G.M. Constantinides, M. Harris
and R. Stulz, Elsevier Science B.V.
Bekaert, Geert and Guojun Wu (2000): “Asymmetric Volatility and Risk in Equity
Markets”, The Review of Financial Studies, 13, 1-42.
Benartzi, Shlomo and Richard H. Thaler (1995): “Myopic Loss Aversion and the Equity
Premium Puzzle”, Quartely Journal of Economics, 110, 73-92.
Benartzi, Shlomo and Richard H. Thaler (1999): “Risk Aversion or Myopia? Choices in
Repeated Gambles and Retirement Investments”, Management Science, 45, 364-381.
Black, Fischer and Myron Scholes (1973): “The Valuation of Options and Corporate
Liabilities”, Journal of Political Economy, 81, 637-654.
Black, Fischer (1976):”Studies of Stock Prices Volatility Changes”, Proceedings of 1976
Meetings of the American Statistical Association, Business and Economic Statistics
Section, 177-181.
Black, Fischer (1986): “Presidential address: Noise”, Journal of Finance, 41,529-543.
Bliss, Robert R., and Nokolaos Panigirtzglou, (2004): “ Option-Implied Risk Aversion
Estimates”, Forthcoming in Journal of Finance.
Bollerslev, Tim, (1986):“ Generalized Autoregressive Conditional Heteroske-dasticity“,
Journal of Econometrics, 31, 307-327.
Bollerslev, Tim and Hao Zhou (2003):”Volatility Puzzles: A Unified Framework for
Gauging Return-Volatility Regressions”, Working Paper of the National Science
Foundation.
Bossaerts, Peter (2002): “The paradox of asset pricing”, Princeton University Press,
Princeton N.J.
Brav, Alon, George M. Constantinides, and Christopher C. Geczy (2002): “Asset Pricing
with Heterogenous Consumers and Limited Participation: Empirical Evidence”,
Journal of Political Economy, 110, 793-824.
Breeden, D., (1979):”An intertemporal asset pricing model with stochastic consumption and
investment opportunities”, Journal of Financial Economics, 7, 265-296.
Brown Gregory W. (1999) “Volatility, Sentiment, and Noise Traders”, Financial Analysts
Journal, vol., March-April, 82-90.
Stock Markets Volatility: A Puzzle? Boris F. Papa
- 75 -
Campbell, John Y, Andrew W. Lo, and Craig MacKinlay (1997): “The Econometrics of
Financial Markets”, Princeton University Press, Princeton N.J.
Campbell, John Y (1999): “Asset Prices, Consumption and the Business Cycle”, Handbook
of Macroeconomics, Vol. 1C, John Taylor and Michael Woodford eds., Amsterdam:
North-Holland.
Campbell, John Y, and John Cochrane (1999): “By force of Habit: A Consumption-Based
Explanation of Aggregate Stock Market Behaviour”, Journal of Political Economy,
107, 202-251.
Campbell, John Y, and John Cochrane (2000): “Explaining the Poor Performance of
Consumption-based Asset Pricing Models”, Journal of Finance, 107, 202-251.
Campbell, John Y, (2000): “Asset Pricing at the Millennium”, Journal of Finance, 55, 2863-
2878.
Campbell, John Y, and L. Hentschel, (1992): “No News Is Good News: An Asymmetric
Model of Changing Volatility Returns”, Journal of Financial Economics, 31, 281-
318.
Canina, Linda and Stephen Figlewski (1993): “The information Content of Implied
Volatility”, The Review of Financial Studies, 6, 659-682.
Christie, A. (1982): “The Stochastic Behaviour of Common Stock Variances: Value,
Leverage and Interest Rate Effects”, Journal of Financial Economics, 10, 407-432.
Cochrane John H, (2001); “ Asset Pricing”, Princeton University Press, Princeton N.J.
Cochrane John H, (2001); “ A Rehabilitation of Stochastic Discount Factor Methology”,
unpublished Working Paper, University of Chicago.
Constantinides, George M (1990): “Habit Formation: A Resolution of the Equity Premium
Puzzle”, Journal of Political Economy, 94,519-543.
Constantinides, George M and Wayne E. Ferson (1991): “Habit persistence and durability in
aggregate consumption, Empirical Tests”, Journal of Financial Economics, 29, 199-
240.
Constantinides, George M (2002): “Rational Asset Prices”, Journal of Finance, 57, 1567-
1591.
Dalang, R.C., A. Morton, and W. Williger, (1990): “Equivalent Martingale Measures and
No-Arbitrage in Stochastic Securities Market Model, Stochastics and Stochastics
Reports, 29, 185-201.
Day, Theodore E. and Craig M. Lewis (1993): “Forecasting Futures Market Volatility”,
Journal of Derivatives,.Winter.
De Bondt, Werner F.M., and Richard H. Thaler, (1985): “ Does Stock Market Overreact?”,
Journal of Finance, 40, 793-807.
Delbaen, Freddy, and Walter Schachermayer, (1994): “A General Version of the
Fundamental Theorem of Asset Pricing”, Math. Ann., 300, 463-520.
De Long, J.B., A. Shleifer, L.H. Summers, and R.J. Waldmann (1990): “ Noise trader risk in
finacial markets”, Journal of Political Economy, 98, 703-738.
Ding, Z., Granger, C. W. J. and Engle, R.F., (1993): “A Long Memory Property of Stock
Market Returns and New Model”, Journal of Empirical Finance, 1, 83-106.
Duffie, Darrell (2001); “Dynamic Asset Pricing Theory”, Third Edition, Princeton
University Press, Princeton N.J.
Engle, Robert F., (1982):” Autoregressive Conditional Heteroskedasticity with estimates of
the variance of United Kingdom inflation, Econometrica, 50, 987-1007.
Engle, Robert F. and V. Ng, (1993): “ Measuring and Testing Impact News on Volatility”,
Journal of Finance, 48, 1749-1778.
Engle, Robert F., and Andrew J. Patton (2001): “What Good is a Volatility Model?”,
unpublished manuscript, Stern School of Business, New York University.
Epstein, Larry G. (1990): “Risk Aversion and Asset Prices”, Journal of Monetary
Economics, 22, 179-192.
Epstein, Larry G., and Stanley E. Zin (1989): “Substitution, Risk Aversion, and the
Temporal Behaviour of Consumption and Asset Returns: A Theoretical Framework”,
Econometrica, 57, 937-969.
Stock Markets Volatility: A Puzzle? Boris F. Papa
- 76 -
Epstein, Larry G., and Stanley E. Zin (1990): “First-order Risk and the Equity Premium
Puzzle”, Journal of Monetary Economics, 26, 387-407.
Epstein, Larry G., and Stanley E. Zin (1991): “Substitution, Risk Aversion, and the
Temporal Behaviour of Consumption and Asset Returns: An Empirical Analysis”,
Journal of Political Economy, 99, 263-286.
Fama, Eugene F., and James D. MacBeth, (1973): “Risk return and Equilibrium: Empirical
Tests”, Journal of Financial Political Economy, 71, 607-636.
Fama, Eugene F., and Kenneth R. French, (1988): “Dividend Yields and Expected Stock
Returns”, Journal of Financial Economics, 22, 3-25.
Fama, Eugene F., and Kenneth R. French, (1992): “The cross-section of expected returns”,
Journal of Finance , 47, 427-466.
Fama, Eugene F., and Kenneth R. French, (1993): “Common Risk Factors in the Returns on
Stocks and Bonds”, Journal of Financial Economics; 33, 3-56.
Fama, Eugene F., and Kenneth R. French, (1996): “Multifactor Explanations of Asset
Pricing Anomalies”, Journal of Finance , 51, 55-84.
Figlewski, Stephen, and Xiaozu Wang, (2000): “Is the “Leverage Effect” a Leverage
Effect?”, Unpublished Working Paper, NYU Stern School of Business, New York, 1-
40.
French, Kenneth R., and James M. Poterba, (1991): “ Investor Diversification and
International Equity Markets”, American Economic Review, 81, 222-226.
Glosten, L.R., R. Jagannathan and D. E. Rumkle, (1993): „ On the Relation between the
Expected Value and the Volatility of the Nominal Excess Return on Stocks”, Journal
of Finance, 48, 1779-1801.
Gollier, Christian (2001): “The Economics of Risk and Time”, MIT Press.
Griffin, Ed (1997): “A First Look at Communication Theory”, McGraw-Hill, inc.
Hamilton, James D. (1994): “Time Series Analysis”, Princeton University Press, Princeton
N.J..
Hansen, Lars P., and Ravi Jagannathan (1991): “Implications of Security Market Data for
Models of Dynamic Economies”, Journal of Political Economy, 99 225-262.
Hansen, Lars P., and Ravi Jagannathan (1997): “Assessing Specification Errors in Stochastic
Discount Factor Models”, Journal of Finance, 52 557-590..
Harvey, Campbell R., and Robert E. Whaley, (1991): “S&P100 Index Option Volatility”,
Journal of Finance, 46, 1151-1161.
Hens, T., K. R. Schenk-Hoppé, (2001): “Evolution of Portfolio Rules in Incomplete
Markets“, Institute for Empirical Research in Economics, University of Zurich,
Working Paper No. 74.
Hens, T., K. R. Schenk-Hoppé, M. Stalder, (2002): “An application of Evolutionary Finance
to Firms Listed in the Swiss Market Index“, Institute for Empirical Research in
Economics, University of Zurich, Working Paper No. 128.
Hens, Thorsten, and Beate Pilgrim (2003): “General Equilibrium Foundations of Finance,
Structure of Incomplete Markets Models”, Kluwer Academic Publisher.
Huang, Chi-fu, and Robert H. Litzenberger, (1988): “Foundations for Financial Economics”,
Amsterdam: North-Holland.
Hull, John C., (1996): “Options, Futures, and Other Derivative Securities”, Prentice Hall
International Editions.
Ingersoll, Jonathan E. Jr., (1987):“ Theory of Financial Decision Making“.
Jegadeesh, Narashimhan, and Sheridan Titman, (1993): “Returns to buying winners and
selling Losers: Implications for Stock Market Efficiency”, Journal of Finance, 48,
65-91.
Jegadeesh, Narashimhan, and Sheridan Titman, (2001): “Profitability of Momentum
Strategies: An Evaluation of Alternative Explanations”, Journal of Fiance, 56, 699-
720.
Jagannathan, Ravi, and Zhenyu Wang (1996): “The Conditional CAPM and the Cross-
Section of Expected Returns”, Journal of Finance, 51, 3-53.
Stock Markets Volatility: A Puzzle? Boris F. Papa
- 77 -
Jagannathan, Ravi, and Zhenyu Wang (2002): “Empirical Evaluation of Asset-Pricing
Models: A Comparison of SDF and Beta Methods”, Journal of Finance, 57, 2337-
2367.
Lamberton, Damien, and Bernard Lapeyre (1996): “Introduction to Stochastic Calculus
Applied to Fianace”, Chapman & Hall/CRC.
LeRoy, Stephen F, and Jan Werner (2001): “Principles of Financial Economics”, Cambridge
University Press U.K..
Lintner, J., (1965):”The valuation of risk assets and the selection of risky investments in
stock portfolios and capital budgets”, Review Economics and Statistics, 47, 13-37.
List, John A. (2004): “ Neoclassical Theory versus Prospect Theory: Evidence from the
Marketplace”, forthcoming in Econometrica, 1-18.
Levy, Haim, Enrico De Giorgi and Thorsten Hens (2003): “Two Paradigms and Nobel Prizes
in Economics: A Contradiction or Coexistence?”, Unpublished paper, Institute for
Empirical Research in Economics of the University Zurich.
Lucas, Robert E., Jr., (1978): “Asset Prices in an Exchange Economy”, Econometrica, 46,
1429-1446.
Magill, Michael and Martine Quinzii, (1996):” The Theory of Incomplete Markets”, volume
1, MIT-Press, London.
Maheu, John M., and Thomas H. McCurdy (2000): “Identifying Bull and Bear Markets in
Stock Returns”, Journal of Business&Economic Statistics, 18, 1-32.
Mehra, Rajnish, and Edward C. Prescott (1985): “The Equity Premium: A Puzzle” Journal of
Monetary Economics, 15, 145-161.
Mehra, Rajnish, and Edward C. Prescott (1988): “The Equity Risk Premium: A Solution”
Journal of Monetary Economics, 22, 133-136.
Merton, Robert C (1969): “Lifetime Portfolio Selection Under Uncertainty: The Continuous
Time Case”, Review of Economics and Statistics, 51, 247-257.
Merton, Robert C. (1973): “An Intertemporal Capital Asset Pricing Model”, Econometrica,
41, 867-887.
Merton, Robert C. (1974): “The Theory of Rational Option Pricing”, Bell Journal of
Economics and Management Science, 4, 141-183.
Merton, Robert C. (1992): “Continuous-Time Finance”, Revised Edition, Blackwell
Publishers, Cambridge, MA.
Montier, James (2002): “Behavioural Finance, Insights into Irrational Minds and Markets,
Wiley Finance, John Wiley & Sons Ltd.
Musiela, Marek, and Marek Rutkowski (1998): “Martingale Methods in Financial
Modelling”, Springer-Verlag Berlin Heidelberg.
Neilson, William S. and Jill Stowe (2001): “A Further Examination of Cumulative Prospect
Theory Parameterisations”, unpublished Working Paper, Department of Economics
Texas A&M University, 1-25.
Nelson, Daniel B., (1991):“Conditional Heteroskedasticity in Asset Returns: A New
Approach, Econometrica, 59, 347-370.
Kahneman, D., and A. Tversky, (1979): “Prospect Theory: An analysis of Decision under
Risk“, Econometrica, 47, 263-291.
Kan, Raymond, and Guofu Zhou (1999): “ A Critique of the Stochastic Discount Factor
Methodology”, Journal of Finance, 54 1221-1248.
Kocherlakota, Narayana R. (1990): “Disentangling the Coefficient of Relative Risk Aversion
from the Elasticity of Intertemporal Substitution: An Irrelevance Result”, Journal of
Finance, 45, 175-190.
Kocherlakota, Narayana R. (1996): “The Equity Premium: It’s still a Puzzle?”, Journal of
Economic Literature, 34, 42-71.
Olsen, Robert A. (1998) “Behavioral Finance and Its Implications for Stock-Price
Volatility”, Financial Analysts Journal, vol., March-April, 10-18.
Pagan, Adrian R., and William G. Schwert (1990): “Alternative Models for Conditional
Stock Volatility”, Journal of Econometrics, 45, 267-290.
Pan, Jun (2002): “ The Jump-Risk Premia Implicit in Options: Evidence from an Integrated
Time-Series Study, Journal of Financial Economics, 63, 3-50.
Stock Markets Volatility: A Puzzle? Boris F. Papa
- 78 -
Pettengill, Glenn N., Sridhar Sundara, and Ike Mathur (1995): “The conditional Relation
between Beta and Returns”, Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 30, 101-
115.
Poterba, James M., and Lawrence H. Summers (1986): “The Persistence of Volatility and
Stock Market Fluctuations”, American Economic Review, 76, 1142-1151.
Poterba, James M., and Lawrence H. Summers (1988): “Mean Reversion in Stock Prices:
Evidence and Implications”, Journal of Financial Economics, 22, 27-59.
Protter, P.(1990): “Stochastic Integartion and Differential Equations”. Springer-Verlag
Berlin Heidelberg New York.
Rietz, Thomas A. (1988): “The Equity Risk Premium: A Solution” Journal of Monetary
Economics, 22, 117-131.
Roll, R. (1977): “A critique of the asset pricing theory's tests: Part I”. Journal of Financial
Economics, 4, 129-76.
Ross, S.A. (1976): “The arbitrage theory of capital asset pricing”, Journal of Economic
Theory, 13, 341-60.
Ross, S.A. (2001): “Closed End Funds: A Neo-classical look at Behavioural Finance”,
Working Paper, MIT, Keynote Address to the EFMA Conference, Lugano, June
2001.
Rubinstein, Mark (2001): “Rational Markets: Yes or No? The Affirmative Case”, Financial
Analyst Journal, May/June, pp. 15-29.
Shefrin, Hersh M. and Meir Statman (1985): “ The Disposition to Sell Winners too early and
Ride Losers too long”, Journal of Finance, 40, 777-790.
Shefrin, Hersh M. (2000): “Beyond Greed and Fear”, Harvard Business School Press,
Boston, Massachusetts.
Shiller Rober J. (1990): “Speculative Prices and Popular Models”, Journal of Economic
Perspectives, 2, 55-65.
Shiller Robert J., (1999): “Human Behavior and the Efficiency of the Financial System”,
Handbook of Macroeconomics, Vol. 1C, John Taylor and Michael Woodford eds.,
Amsterdam: North-Holland.
Shiller Rober J. (2000): “Irrational Exuberance”, Princeton University Press, Princeton, New
Jersey.
Schwert, William G., (1989): “Why Does Stock Market Volatility Change Over Time”,
Journal of Finance, 44, 1115-1153.
Schwert, William G., (1990): “Stock Volatility and the Crash of 1987”, The Review of
Financial Studies, 3, 77-102.
Schwert, William G., (1990): “Indexes of U.S. Stock Prices from 1802 to 1987”, Journal of
Business, 63, 399-426.
Schwert, William G. (2002): “Stock Volatility in the New Millenium: How Wacky is
Nasdaq?”, Journal of Monetary Economics, 49, 3-26.
Thaler, Richard H. (1999): “The End of Behavioural Finance”, Financial Analyst Journal,
Nov/Dec, pp. 12-17.
Thaler, Richard H. (2000): “From Homo Economicus to Homo Sapiens”, Journal of
Economic Perspectives, 14, 133-141.
Tversky, Amos and Daniel Kahneman (1992): “Advances in Prospect Theory: Cumulative
Representation of Uncertainty”, Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 5, 297-323.
Ziegler, Alexandre (2002): “Why does Implied Risk Aversion smile?”, University of
Lausanne and Fame, Research Paper, 47, 1-30.
Zivot Eric, and Jiahui Wang (2003): “Modeling Financial Time Series with S-Plus”,
Insightful Corporation.
Weil, Philippe (1989): “The Equity Premium Puzzle and the Risk-Free Rate Puzzle” Journal
of Monetary Economics, 24, 401-421.
Weil, Philippe (1990): “Nonexpected Utility in Macroeconomics” The Quartely Journal of
Economics, 24, 29-42.
Williams, David (1991): “Probability with Martingales”, Cambridge Mathematical
Textbooks, Cambridge University Press.
Các file đính kèm theo tài liệu này:
- BorisPapa.pdf