The results in tables 2 are consistent with the model and support the two first
hypotheses. Firstly, entrepreneurship has statistically significant and positive
contribution to long-run growth from model 2 to model 5. These results support the first
hypothesis that entrepreneurship as a mechanism for knowledge spillover is integral to
long-run economic growth.
Secondly, agglomeration plays the key role in enhancing entrepreneurship’s
contribution to growth (See. Model 1 versus model 2). An area with high density has
an advantage in recognizing and acting on entrepreneurial opportunities. Furthermore,
large population creates a broad variety of demand as well great quantity demanded.
These are fertile sources for entrepreneurial opportunities.
Thirdly, the fact that the coefficient of the interaction term between
entrepreneurship and dummy is statistically significant in Model 5 supports the second
hypothesis of the study. Entrepreneurship’s importance to economic growth varies
among stages of development. Particularly, entrepreneurship contributes to economic
growth more in innovation-driven economies than in the investment-driven because
knowledge is the primary factor to innovation-driven economies.
There are three valuable findings about the determinants of entrepreneurship in
table 3. Firstly, human capital plays an integral role in facilitating entrepreneurship (see
model 4 and 5). Each person has his own knowledge specific to time and place. With
this specific knowledge, some people can notice profits opportunities that other people
cannot notice. For example, a song should be written by composers but not engineers
(Holcombe, 1998).
Secondly, infrastructure has a significantly positive effect on entrepreneurship in
model 2 and 3. This fact supports the function (14). Good infrastructure is a facilitator.
On the contrary, poor infrastructure is a barrier to entrepreneurship.Finally, the fact that coefficients of both Log(y) and Log(y)xD are statistically
significant implies that entrepreneurship considerably varies between various stages.
Particularly, the same change in output level makes a change in entrepreneurship
greater in investment-driven economies than in innovation-driven economies. This
result also supports the third hypothesis.
8 trang |
Chia sẻ: hachi492 | Ngày: 18/01/2022 | Lượt xem: 256 | Lượt tải: 0
Bạn đang xem nội dung tài liệu Entrepreneurship and economic growth along stages of development, để tải tài liệu về máy bạn click vào nút DOWNLOAD ở trên
WORKING PAPER SERIES
School of Economics
University of Economics Ho Chi Minh City
ENTREPRENEURSHIP AND ECONOMIC GROWTH
ALONG STAGES OF DEVELOPMENT
Minh H. Do
Abstract
Economies at different stages embody diverse characteristics in the term of underlying forces, external
environment, and government policy because of their disparate primary inputs. While private inputs, e.g.,
capital are critical to growth through accumulation in the investment-driven economies, knowledge indeed
is the main input bringing about productivity-based growth in innovation-driven economies, e.g., the US
with Silicon Valley. However, the investment-driven economies also have new knowledge flowing from
advanced economies through foreign trade and FDI and therefore requires entrepreneurship either.
This study aims at: (1) determining whether entrepreneurship, as a mechanism for knowledge spillover, is
integral to growth; (2) finding out whether entrepreneurship’s contribution to growth varies among stages;
and (3) determining if entrepreneurship differs among stages.
Working Paper Series
UEHSEWP #004/2017
School of Economics
University of Economics Ho Chi Minh City
Address: 1A Hoang Dieu, Phu Nhuan, Ho Chi Minh City, Vietnam
Phone: +84-28-3844-8222
Email: kkt@ueh.edu.vn
Website: www.se.ueh.edu.vn
ENTREPRENEURSHIP AND ECONOMIC GROWTH ALONG STAGES
OF DEVELOPMENT
Minh H. Do
1. Introduction
In the second half of the 20th century, productivity rather than capital accumulation
was academically considered a primary determinant of long-run economic growth in
both exogenous and endogenous growth theories. The world also has witnessed few
OECD nations, including the United States (US), the United Kingdom (UK), and
Singapore and China in recent years (Wei, Xie, & Zhang, 2017) came to strategies for
structural transformation from investment-driven to an innovation-driven economy.
Therefore, technological knowledge has become the predominant factor in the
innovation-driven economies because of its integral role in enhancing productivity.
More importantly, Romer (1990) developed the theory of endogenous technology,
which demonstrates the significance of conscious investments in new knowledge, e.g.,
R&D activities to technological change. Consequently, economic growth is
endogenously determined by relevant policies, e.g., innovation policy. However, the
theory came with the hypothetical assumption that knowledge spillover automatically
occurs without specifying any mechanism.
Since 1990, the resurgence of small-scale firms in transformed economies and
bursts of studies incorporating entrepreneurship into the growth economics marked the
highest peak of entrepreneurship literature and an alternative direction in the
manipulation of economic growth. The knowledge spillover theory of entrepreneurship
was an exemplification. In this theory, knowledge filter1 which is defined as the
difference between new knowledge and economically relevant knowledge (David B.
Audretsch & Keilbach, 2007) was introduced and furthermore could be narrowed down
by entrepreneurship. In other words, entrepreneurship could be either considered as a
mechanism for knowledge spillover or defined as the process of exploiting the
unexploited profit opportunities (Kirzner, 1973). Therefore, this study combines the
knowledge spillover theory of entrepreneurship with endogenous growth theories.
Economies at different stages embody diverse characteristics in the term of
underlying forces, external environment, and government policy because of their
disparate primary inputs. While private inputs, e.g., capital are critical to growth
through accumulation in the investment-driven economies, knowledge indeed is the
main input bringing about productivity-based growth in innovation-driven economies,
e.g., the US with Silicon Valley. However, the investment-driven economies also have
new knowledge flowing from advanced economies through foreign trade and FDI and
therefore requires entrepreneurship either.
This study aims at: (1) determining whether entrepreneurship, as a mechanism for
knowledge spillover, is integral to growth; (2) finding out whether entrepreneurship’s
contribution to growth varies among stages; and (3) determining if entrepreneurship
differs among stages.
2. Stages of Economies
2.1. Investment-driven economies
“The output is produced with the help of two factors of production, capital, and
labor. Technological possibilities are represented by a production function” (Solow,
1956, p. 66). Solow (1956) considered capital and labor the primary factors to the
manufacturing and postulated growth in output just takes place as economies
accumulate capital. These factors have the attributes of rivalry and excludability.
Therefore, the production process could be operated the most efficient at the large scale.
This was a justification for the dominance of large corporations and the declining
importance of entrepreneurship and small business in Europe and North America during
the post-war era from 1945 to the late 1980s (Audretsch & Thurik, 2004). The large
corporations featuring mass production2 were the engine of the economies. As a result,
the policymakers were confronted with the tradeoffs between efficiency brought about
by the large corporation on the one hand and political and economic decentralization
associated with small firms on the contrary (Audretsch & Thurik, 2004). The economies
identified with efficiency focus, the dominance of large corporations, stability,
homogeneity, and continuity are called investment-driven (or managed) economies
(Audretsch & Thurik, 2001). Moreover, entrepreneurship was just a new scientific
research programme in the field of business administration in this era (Cuervo, Ribeiro,
& Roig, 2007).
2.2. Innovation-driven economies
In the early 1990s, the trend was reversed in the same economies. Particularly, the
sales share of small firms in the United States (US) increased from one-fifth in 1976 to
one-quarter in 1986. Employment share in the manufacturing of small companies from
the 1970s to the 1980s significantly increased in Netherlands (68.3% - 71.8%); UK
(30.1% - 39.9%) and North of Italy (44.3% - 55.2%) (David B. Audretsch & Thurik,
2004). This was called the emergence of entrepreneurship and small firms. Research on
entrepreneurship also exploded into an avid interest in political and academic fields
upon the arrival of Birch’s (1979) report “The Job Generation Process.” This report
showed new firms accounted for up to 50% new jobs created in the US from 1969 to
1976 (Cuervo et al., 2007).
The reemergence of entrepreneurship and small firms can be justified by the
enormous significance of knowledge to economic growth (Audretsch & Thurik, 2004).
Additionally, in the theory of technological change developed by Romer (1990)
knowledge was considered a source of technological change. In practice, the
investment-driven economies in the previous period, e.g., the US and the UK were
transforming into the innovation-driven economies which were dictated by the
dominance of knowledge as the source of comparative advantage. The innovation-
driven economy can be identified with flexibility, turbulence, diversity, novelty, and
innovation (David B. Audretsch & Thurik, 2004).
3. Exogenous Entrepreneurial Opportunities
“Entrepreneurs like (Richard) Branson are bornFrom family, they inherit may
traits key to entrepreneurship: creativity, drive, a willingness to take risks.” (Hopkins,
2004). This quote reflects exactly the core of entrepreneurship literature.
In entrepreneurship literature, the context in the term of knowledge surrounding
entrepreneurs is assumed fixed while the cognitive process of entrepreneurial
opportunities and propensity to act on those opportunities through a start-up totally
depend on individual-specific traits, characteristics, and ability (Audretsch & Keilbach,
2007). Particularly, those individual-specific characteristics including, attitude to risk,
desire for autonomy and self-sufficiency; availability and accessibility to a wide range
2 Mass production means production of highly standardized products in large volume.
of resources3 (Eckhardt & Shane, 2003; Shane & Venkataraman, 2000) totally account
for the variations in entrepreneurship.
The literature seems to have no policy implications for economic growth because it
could not show sources of entrepreneurial opportunities (Audretsch et al., 2006;
Holcombe, 1998) and posits that entrepreneurs are not made but born. Section 5
employs the knowledge spillover theory of entrepreneurship (KSTE) to deal with this
drawback of entrepreneurship literature.
4. Modern Growth Theories
4.1. Post-war era and physical capital
The post-war era featured: (1) Solow or investment-driven economies, which are
appropriately explained by Solow-Swan model and have consisted of physical capital-
based economic activities efficiently conducted by economic agents including laborers
and capitalists in large-scale operations to achieve economic growth (David B.
Audretsch, Keilbach, & Lehmann, 2006); (2) the focus on efficiency associated with
large corporations; (3) minor significance of entrepreneurs because of the competitive
assumption (Leibenstein, 1968); (4) the 3rd stage of entrepreneurship as a scientific
research programme from scratch (Cuervo et al., 2007).
4.2. Globalization era and knowledge capital
The new era was marked by the significant advances in technology, especially the
rise of ICT4 (Davis et al., 2002; Heizer & Render, 2011). The ICT has carried wide-
ranging implications for the corporate organization, globalization, even the demise of
the communist system, and entrepreneurship (Thurik et al., 2013). As a result, this era
featured: (1) the emergence of innovation-driven economies, consisting of economic
activities primarily based on knowledge and depending on the role of entrepreneurship
in innovation process (Audretsch & Thurik, 2001; Audretsch et al., 2006); (2) the shift
in comparative advantage to knowledge-based economic activities; (3) the structural
transformation in some nations e.g., US or UK; (4) the emergence of entrepreneurship;
(5) knowledge as the primary input to economic activities.
4.3. FDI and trade
The Heckscher-Ohlin model postulated that increased openness benefits countries
through static effect, e.g., resource allocation. However, there exit many implicit
benefits (Cameron, 1998). Firstly, trade partners can gain the flow of ideas, which is
often called diffusion of knowledge as well as affect domestic rate of innovation
(Cameron, 1998). The diffusion of knowledge takes place as the domestic producers
are in contact with the most efficient foreign producers as well as other local producers
from which they can learn and improve their technologies (Buera & Oberfield, 2016).
Secondly, the foreign direct investment (FDI) often is understood as bringing economic
growth and know-how to developing countries (Lagace, 2002). Particularly, the foreign
firms, which usually come from developed nations, establish their businesses, including
build manufacturing plant, recruit and train local workforce, import machine tools and
material, deploy procedures for various functions in the host country. Through that
3 Financial capital, human capital, social capital and experiential capital; information and social capital;
required skills and experience for starting up
4 The ICT was derived from three inventions ranging from information to communication technologies.
Those inventions are the transistor by Bell Labs, 1947; integrated circuit by Texas Instrument, 1958 and
microprocessor by Intel, 1971 (Thurik, Stam, & Audretsch, 2013)
establishment of new FDI firms, knowledge can be learned by local workforce directly
and quickly. Therefore, FDI is an efficient channel through which knowledge can spill
over (Cameron, 1998)
5. Endogenous Entrepreneurial Opportunities
According to the knowledge spillover theory of entrepreneurship (Audretsch &
Keilbach, 2007; Audretsch et al., 2006), the source of entrepreneurial opportunities is
endogenous, as opposed to exogenous as assumed in the literature of entrepreneurship.
Particularly, entrepreneurship is related either to knowledge or economic growth.
6. Empirical Model and Results
The study estimates two equations – one for economic output and the other for
entrepreneurship. Firstly, the production function consists of both private factors,
knowledge capital, and human capital. Additionally, the theory of technological change
features the value of λ less than one. λ reflects the tacit knowledge spillover among
researchers. Hence, the high value of λ means R&D activities are productive. More
importantly, the value of λ is determined by entrepreneurship and by agglomeration.
log(𝑦) = 𝑎0 + 𝑎1𝐴 + 𝑎2𝐼𝑁𝐹𝑅𝐴𝑆𝑇 + 𝑎3𝐻𝐶 + 𝑎4𝑘 + 𝑎5𝐿 + 𝑎6𝐴 × 𝐸𝑁𝑇𝑅𝐸
+ 𝑎7𝐴 × 𝐴𝐺𝐺𝐿 + 𝑎8𝐸𝑁𝑇𝑅𝐸 + 𝑎9𝐴𝐺𝐺𝐿 + 𝑎10𝐸𝑁𝑇𝑅𝐸 × 𝐷
Secondly, the entrepreneurial opportunity is not exogenous at all but is the function of
the purposive investment in knowledge. Economies also gain new knowledge from
engaging in international trade or receiving FDI from foreign countries. Therefore,
entrepreneurship is determined by the availability of opportunities, the permeability of
knowledge filter and some barriers – government size.
𝐸𝑁𝑇𝑅𝐸 = 𝑏0 + 𝑏1𝐴 + 𝑏2𝐹𝐷𝐼 + 𝑏3𝐺𝑂𝑉 + 𝑏4𝑊 + 𝑏5𝐿𝑜𝑔(𝑌) + 𝑏6𝑃𝐴𝑇𝐸𝑁𝑇
+ 𝑏7𝐴𝐺𝐺𝐿 + 𝑏8𝐼𝑁𝐹𝑅𝐴𝑆𝑇 + 𝑏9𝐻𝐶 + 𝑏10𝐿𝑜𝑔(𝑌) × 𝐷
The study adds dummy variables into equations to find out whether the contribution
of entrepreneurship to economic growth differs significantly between stages; and
whether entrepreneurship varies between stages. (Entrepreneurial economies take value
of 1, and managed economies take value of 0). It uses the panel data and the two-stage
least squares to estimate the system of two equations. The panel data is made of 331
observations on 35 OECD nations from 2002 – 2014.
Table 1: Variable definition and data source
VARIABLE DEFINITION SOURCE
A; Technological knowledge
stock
R&D expenditures (%GDP) WDI
PATENT: Knowledge filter Total patent application (resident as well as non-
resident)
WDI
ENTRE: Entrepreneurship New registrations per 1000 people ages 15 - 64 WDI
FDI: Openness of the economy FDI net inflow (%GDP) WDI
GOV: Barrier to entrepreneur General government final consumption
expenditure (%GDP)
WDI
INFRAST: Infrastructure Internet user per 100 people WDI
HC: Human capital Education expenditure (%GDP) WDI
K: Physical capital Gross fixed capital formation (%GDP) WDI
Y: Output per capita GDP per capita, PPP, (2011USD) WDI
W: Wage Average annual wage OECD
L: Labor in industry (Excl Agri) Employment in industry (% total employment) WDI
AGGL: Agglomeration Large city population (%Urban population) WDI
HC: Human capital Education expenditure (%GDP) WDI
Table 2: Regression results for Log(y)
Model 1 Model 2 Model 3 Model 4 Model 5
Intercept 4.3 (0.00) 4.39 (0.00) 4.39 (0.00) 4.39 (0.00) 4.16 (0.00)*
A 0.08 (0.00) 0.13 (0.00) 0.13 (0.00) 0.13 (0.00) 0.18 (0.00)*
INFRAST 0.001 (0.00) 0.000 (0.38) 0.000 (0.38) 0.000 (0.38) 0.00 (0.44)
HC 0.01 (0.01) 0.02 (0.00) 0.02 (0.00) 0.02 (0.00) 0.014 (0.02)**
K 0.00 (0.72) 0.001 (0.43) 0.001 (0.43) 0.001 (0.43) 0.00 (0.73)
L -0.006 (0.00) -0.007 (0.00) -0.007 (0.00) -0.007 (0.00) -0.00 (0.02)**
AxENTRE -0.002 (0.64) -0.02 (0.06) -0.02 (0.06) -0.02 (0.06) -0.03 (0.00)*
AxAGGL -0.001 (0.00) -0.00 (0.24) -0.000 (0.24) -0.000 (0.24) -0.00 (0.00)*
ENTRE 0.0003 (0.73) 0.036
(0.07)***
0.036 (0.07) 0.036 (0.07) 0.05 (0.00)*
AGGL
-0.003
(0.054)
-0.003
(0.054)
-0.003
(0.054)
ENTRExD
0.03 (0.00)*
Adj-Rsrq 0.54 0.44 0.44 0.44 0.53
Note: p-value in brackets
* Statistically significant at the two-tailed test for 99% level of confidence
** Statistically significant at the two-tailed test for 95% level of confidence
*** Statistically significant at the two-tailed test for 90% level of confidence
Table 3: Regression results for entrepreneurship
Model 1 Model 2 Model 3 Model 4 Model 5
Intercept -92.9 (0.00) 118.7 (0.00) 91.6 (0.03) -133 (0.00) -61.8 (0.1)
A -1.125 (0.00) -1.29 (0.00) -1.39 (0.00) -1.5 (0.00) -1.32 (0.00)*
FDI -0.00 (0.97) -0.019 (0.37) -0.01 (0.47) 0.0009 (0.68) 0.004 (0.83)
GOV -0.021 (0.78) 0.045 (0.53) 0.007 (0.92) -0.136 (0.1) -0.164 (0.02)**
W -0.00 (0.09) 0.00 (0.00) 0.000 (0.02) -0.00 (0.00) -0.00 (0.64)
Logy 22.7 (0.00) -30.3 (0.00) -23.7 (0.02) 32.11(0.00) 14.22
(0.10)***
PATENT -0.00 (0.24) -0.00 (0.00) -0.00 (0.06) 0.00 (0.3) -0.00 (0.08)***
AGGL 0.1 (0.00) 0.14 (0.00) 0.133 (0.00) 0.08 (0.00)
INFRAST
0.14 (0.00) 0.13 (0.00)
0.076 (0.00)*
HC
0.37 (0.16) 1.3 (0.00) 1.33 (0.00)*
LOGYxD
-0.95 (0.00)*
Adj-Rsrq 0.06 0.19 0.25 0.04 0.28
Note: p-value in brackets
* Statistically significant at the two-tailed test for 99% level of confidence
** Statistically significant at the two-tailed test for 95% level of confidence
*** Statistically significant at the two-tailed test for 90% level of confidence
The results in tables 2 are consistent with the model and support the two first
hypotheses. Firstly, entrepreneurship has statistically significant and positive
contribution to long-run growth from model 2 to model 5. These results support the first
hypothesis that entrepreneurship as a mechanism for knowledge spillover is integral to
long-run economic growth.
Secondly, agglomeration plays the key role in enhancing entrepreneurship’s
contribution to growth (See. Model 1 versus model 2). An area with high density has
an advantage in recognizing and acting on entrepreneurial opportunities. Furthermore,
large population creates a broad variety of demand as well great quantity demanded.
These are fertile sources for entrepreneurial opportunities.
Thirdly, the fact that the coefficient of the interaction term between
entrepreneurship and dummy is statistically significant in Model 5 supports the second
hypothesis of the study. Entrepreneurship’s importance to economic growth varies
among stages of development. Particularly, entrepreneurship contributes to economic
growth more in innovation-driven economies than in the investment-driven because
knowledge is the primary factor to innovation-driven economies.
There are three valuable findings about the determinants of entrepreneurship in
table 3. Firstly, human capital plays an integral role in facilitating entrepreneurship (see
model 4 and 5). Each person has his own knowledge specific to time and place. With
this specific knowledge, some people can notice profits opportunities that other people
cannot notice. For example, a song should be written by composers but not engineers
(Holcombe, 1998).
Secondly, infrastructure has a significantly positive effect on entrepreneurship in
model 2 and 3. This fact supports the function (14). Good infrastructure is a facilitator.
On the contrary, poor infrastructure is a barrier to entrepreneurship.
Finally, the fact that coefficients of both Log(y) and Log(y)xD are statistically
significant implies that entrepreneurship considerably varies between various stages.
Particularly, the same change in output level makes a change in entrepreneurship
greater in investment-driven economies than in innovation-driven economies. This
result also supports the third hypothesis.
Các file đính kèm theo tài liệu này:
- entrepreneurship_and_economic_growth_along_stages_of_develop.pdf